Cartel Capers

A blog about cartels, competition and compliance

100 Blawg Honoree
  • Home
  • Bob Connolly
    • Contact
  • Antitrust Resources
  • Enforcement Agencies
  • Whistleblower Blog

Bid Rigging Prosecution In Canada Hits Another Setback

February 24, 2015 by Robert Connolly

Here’s a quick post by James Musgrove and Joshua Chad about an interesting case in Canada.

******************

Bid Rigging Prosecution Hits Another Setback

The trial judge in a high profile bid rigging case with respect to federal government procurement has directed that a verdict of not guilty be entered for one of the individual accused, ruling that there was no reasonable possibility of a conviction. The trial continues against a number of other accused. This is not the first setback for the Crown in the case. In a pre-trial motion the same judge, Judge Warkentin, ruled that the Competition Act’s provisions allowing the admission of documentary evidence to prove the truth of the matters set out in the documents was unconstitutional in a criminal case. Please see the full news report here.

 

 

Filed Under: Blog

News From Taiwan—Guest Post by Professor Andy C.M. Chen

February 23, 2015 by Robert Connolly

I am pleased to post this update by Dr. Andy C.M. Chen, a professor at Chung Yuan Christian University in Taiwan. Professor Chen is a graduate of Northwestern School of Law and was formerly a member of the Taiwan Fair Trade Commission. As you will see from Professor Chen’s post, cartels are defined quite differently in Taiwan than they are in the United States.  Professor Chen’s personal web page can be found here.

***************************************************

Amendments to Taiwan Fair Trade Act

The recent amendments of the Taiwan Fair Trade Act were published by the Office of the President and officially took effect on February 4, 2015. The amendments cover nearly 70% of the provisions in the TFTA and are the most extensive revision ever since the Act was enacted in 1992. The main changes include the followings:

  1. Pre-merger notification

1.1. Shares held by or business turnover of the companies affiliated with the merging parties shall be included in the determination of whether the threshold for filing pre-merger notification has been crossed.

1.2. Individuals or groups who are not legal persons but enjoy de facto control of the merging companies could also be subject to the duty of filing pre-merger notification.

1.3. The Taiwan Fair Trade Commission is authorized to promulgate and apply individual business-turnover thresholds for selected industries.

  1. Cartel

2.1. A provision was added to allow the TFTC to infer the existence of collusive agreements from market structure, characteristics of products or service, cost and profit consideration, economic rationality of conduct under review etc.

2.2 The category of exemptible concerted actions was further expanded to include those that are beneficial to industrial developments, technical innovation or operational efficiency.

  1. Vertical restraints

Resale price maintenance and most non-price vertical restraints are re-characterized as “antitrust” (competition-restraining) rather than unfair-competition violations. Market power will therefore become a prerequisite for initiating investigations. Those types of violation are also to be reviewed under the rule of reason. Business or efficiency justifications for vertical restraints could be raised by the parties.

  1. Investigation

The amendments Incorporate a “suspension and termination” system under which the TFTC could suspend its investigation if the investigated enterprises promise to cease or take measures to correct the collusive conducts. If the promise is eventually implemented, the TFTC has the discretion to terminate the investigation.

  1. Penalties

The maximum administrative fines for “antitrust” violations are doubled. The statute of limitations for conducting administrative investigation has also been increased from 3 years to 5 years. For violations committed by business associations or organizations, participating individual members could also be punished.

  1. Appeal

The sanctioned parties could now appeal directly to the Administrative court without the need to undergo first the proceeding of administrative appeal.

To the disappointment of the TFTC, however, the proposal to empower the TFTC to conduct search and seizure failed to gain the approval from the congress.

For the amended provisions (Traditional Chinese), please refer to http://www.ftc.gov.tw/internet/main/doc/docDetail.aspx?uid=132&docid=167

 

Filed Under: Blog

A Flurry of Activity by the CCI–India Update

February 16, 2015 by Robert Connolly

Today’s guest post by Avinash Amarnath reports on several actions by the Competition Commission  of India

India update 2015 Vol 3

Its been quite a busy fortnight for the Competition Commission of India (CCI) especially on the cartel front. The CCI has issued three substantive decisions (two infringement decisions and one decision finding no infringement after a detailed investigation) last week which I have analysed below.

Another chemist and druggist association penalised

In its ninth decision against various chemist and druggist trade associations in India, the Competition Commission of India (CCI) fined the Himachal Pradesh (a state in India) Chemist and Druggist Association 10% of its average turnover for imposing rules requiring:

  • a no-objection certificate from it before a pharmaceutical company could appoint a stockist in the state of Himachal Pradesh; and
  • requiring compulsory payment of ‘product information service’ charges by the pharmaceutical company before launching a drug in the state.

The CCI found that these rules cumulatively resulted in limiting supply in the market and restricted pharmaceutical companies’ ability to launch new drugs onto the market. The president of the trade association was fined 8% of his average income for his liability as an individual.

An interesting takeaway from this decision is the CCI’s analysis of whether pharmaceutical companies can also be found liable for forming an agreement with the trade association to deny stockistship and limit supplies for the want of a no-objection certificate from the trade association. The CCI found that agreements between pharmaceutical companies and the trade association would not qualify as horizontal agreements (falling under Section 3(3) of the Competition Act) or as vertical agreements (falling under Section 3(4) of the Competition Act) as they are neither engaged in identical or similar trade of goods or provision of services  nor operating at different stages or levels of the production chain. However, relying on a previous decision (Ramakant Kini v. Hirandandani Hospital and Ors, a discussion on which appeared in my first post on Cartel Capers), the CCI observed that such agreements could nonetheless be examined under the general prohibition on anti-competitive agreements (Section 3(1) of the Competition Act) and would be subject to a rule of reason analysis. However, in the instant case, the pharmaceutical companies were not found liable as there was no evidence to indicate an agreement between them and the trade association.

The full order of the CCI can be accessed here.

CCI finds no evidence of a cartel amongst builders but still passes strong observations against exploitative and unfair practices adopted by these builders

 The CCI recently closed its investigation into an alleged cartel among builders in India finding insufficient evidence of a cartel agreement amongst them. The allegation was that the builders had used the Confederation of Real Estate Developers’ Association of India (“CREDAI”), a trade association as a platform to fix the contractual terms to be entered into with their customers. The only evidence found by the CCI was that of commonality of clauses in the contracts, which it held was insufficient to establish collusion. While no penalty was imposed on the parties, the CCI did heavily criticise the contractual terms of the builders and observed that they were unfair and exploitative. The CCI recommended that the parties take appropriate voluntary measures to address these concerns and also emphasized the need for a sectoral regulator in the real estate sector.

An interesting takeaway from this decision is the CCI’s observation on the issue of cross-examination. Under the implementing regulations, the CCI or the Director General (DG) can direct a party to submit evidence through oral or written submission. One of the parties in this case sought cross-examination of the informant. The CCI observed that an opportunity of cross-examination may be granted to the parties only if: a) evidence is led by way of oral submission; and b) the CCI or the DG consider it necessary or expedient; the necessity or expediency depending on the factual matrix of each case. The CCI stated that as a general rule, when information supplied by a party is based on ‘personal knowledge’, the other party should be granted the right to cross-examine the party giving evidence. On the other hand, when the information provided by a party is documentary, the other party need not be granted the right to cross-examine the party giving evidence. This seems to be in contrast to the provisions of the Indian Evidence Act, 1872 (which governs the rules of evidence in regular court proceedings) where a party may be cross-examined in relation to previous statements made by him in writing and relevant to the matter in question.

The full order of the CCI can be accessed here.

CCI finds truckers’ society guilty of cartel and abuse of dominance

The CCI fined the Kiratpur Sahib Truck Operators Co-operative Transport Society Limited, a cooperative society of truck operators in the area of Kiratpur, Punjab and its individual office bearers 10% of the average turnover and 5% of the average incomes respectively for collectively fixing prices for trucking services and limiting supply of trucking services by not allowing non-member truckers to operate in the area.  Interestingly, the CCI found these acts to be in violation of the Competition Act both as a cartel of the individual truckers who were members of the society and as an abuse of dominance by the society. However, the individual members of the society were not fined as they were not investigated or examined by the DG in their individual capacity.

The CCI found that the society itself constituted an ‘enterprise’ (the Indian equivalent of the concept of an ‘undertaking’ under EU competition law) as it was actively engaged in activities relating to provision of freight transport services. The CCI, while noting that trade associations usually do not qualify as ‘enteprises’ as they do not carry on any economic activity themselves, observed that this could only be determined by examining the functional aspects of the activities of the association in each case. In the present case, the CCI found that the society entered into freight transport contracts in its own name and got such contracts executed through its members according to its own internal procedure/ management and the customer had no dealing with the various members directly. The customer made payment for the services to the society who then passed on the payment to the concerned member after retaining a commission/ its own administrative charges. The society was then found to be dominant in the relevant market for provision of services of goods transportation by trucks in and around Kiratpur area in Punjab as there was no other enterprise providing such services in this area. The CCI found that the society had abused its dominance by imposing excessive prices on customers and taking various actions including threats and violence to prevent any other truckers from operating in the area.

The same acts were also found to be amounting to a cartel amongst the individual members of the society who were supposed to operate independently but had instead collectively fixed prices and ensured that no other truckers operated in the area.

It appears odd that the CCI felt the need to penalise the society under both cartel and abuse of dominance provisions especially given the fact that the CCI held upfront that the individual members of the society could not be proceeded against. In my view, what the CCI seems to be getting at is that while the society itself being a dominant enterprise had abused its dominant position in its capacity as an enterprise, the individual members who also constituted enterprises had formed a cartel under the aegis of the society. The logical follow on to this finding, of course, would have been to fine the individual members of the society under the cartel provisions, which was however not done due to due process issues.

The full order of the CCI can be accessed here.

Avinash Amarnath can be reached at Avinash.Amarnath@tta.in.

Filed Under: Blog

A Small Contribution to Antitrust History

February 12, 2015 by Robert Connolly

The end of January marked the two-year anniversary of the closing of the Philadelphia Field Office and its siblings in Atlanta, Cleveland and Dallas. Among the many things I enjoyed during my career at the Antitrust Division was the great history of the institution and antitrust law in general. I remember the Department of Justice’s commemoration of the 100th Anniversary of the Sherman Act on July 20, 1990.  An all-star cast of antitrust luminaries spoke at the event.  The remarks made at that event have been entered in the Congressional record. Being an antitrust junkie, I’ve also enjoyed the history recounted in two excellent books, Thurman Arnold: A Biography by Spencer Weber Waller and Antitrust Stories, edited by Eleanor M. Fox and Daniel A. Crane.

I wanted to add my own small contribution to recording some antitrust history; particularly that of the Philadelphia Field Office.  After the office was closed in January 2013, I wrote an article “A Short History of the Philadelphia Field Office.” More recently I came across a program from an event sponsored by the Historical Society of the United States District Court for the Eastern District of Pennsylvania to commemorate “A Celebration of 50 Years of Antitrust Enforcement: Philadelphia Field Office, Established 1948.”  The program was held on November 3, 1998 and featured many distinguished speakers. Joel I. Klein, Assistant Attorney General, Antitrust Division made the Opening remarks. The event included  remarks by several federal judges, including the Honorable Louis C. Bechtle. The program can be found at PhillyOffice50YearCelebration.

A few of the highlights are:

  •  November 8, 1948      First indictment in U.S. v. Leather and Shoe Finders Association of Philadelphia charging one trade association, two corporations and ten individuals with price-fixing and group boycott. Defendants were fined $1,000 each.
  • June 2, 1950    Prosecution for criminal monopolization. Defendants pled nolo and were fined a total of $11,000.
  • February 16, 1960    First indictments in the Great Electrical Equipment Conspiracy which sent senior executives to jail and also kicked off the modern class action bar.
  • October 29, 1976      US v. Continental Group, the first indictment after the Sherman Act became a felony. Convicted executives were sentenced to jail.
  • 1981     I don’t remember the exact date, but it was the first time (I believe) the office obtained a search warrant.  We had probable cause to believe an executive at one company took the fall for his boss and an agreement setting forth his “compensation” was kept in a bank safe deposit box. Nothing was found.
  • 3/ 24/1982   First indictment of  the office’s 46 road cases. Jury convicted two companies and four individuals.
  • 6/29/1984    Office’s first prosecution based on consensual monitoring.
  • 1/27/1988     Office’s first use of industry wide search warrants during fuel oil investigation.

Some of the office’s most notable cases involved international cartels.  Several of these cases came before international cartels became an Antitrust Division focus.

  • US v. Amir Porat, 17 F. 3d 660 (3d Cir. 1994)

Porat was indicted in 1992 on two counts of making material false declarations before a grand jury that was investigating a bid-rigging scheme between Porat, an Israeli citizen, and two American defense department contractors. The collusion involved contracts in both the U.S. and Israel. It was alleged that Porat took a $200,000 kickback, which was deposited into his Swiss bank account, as part of the bid-rigging scheme—and lied about it before the grand jury. This was one of the wildest cases the office ever had. Porat was indicted under seal and apprehended at the Canadian border as he tried to enter the U.S. The staff had obtained the $200,000 check deposited into his Swiss back account. (Don’t ask me how; I’m sworn to secrecy.) Porat was his own attorney at trial and he was resourceful, charismatic, charming, but ultimately guilty. As part of his defense to show that someone could have opened a Swiss bank account in his name, Porat entered into evidence a Swiss bank account he had opened in the name of one of our prosecutors!  Unfortunately for Porat, that account did not have $200,000 in it.

  • United States v. A&L Mayer Assoc. Inc.  (1996) 

This early international cartel case involved a  prosecution involving price-fixing by Mexican tampico growers who imported the product into the United States. The information/complaint charged the often talked about but rarely seen outside of a law school exam,  horizontal price-fixing agreement among the Mexican tampico companies that was monitored by a resale price-fixing maintenance agreement with their U.S distributors.

  • United States v. UCAR (1998)

The modern era of international cartel enforcement is often considered to start with the Chicago office’s prosecution of ADM in the lysine cartel in 1996. The Dallas Field office followed up with the massive vitamins cartel prosecutions. Philadelphia was next up with the graphite electrodes prosecutions. Graphite electrodes resulted in the Mitsubishi Corp trial and conviction. And, like most international cartels, many distinct cartels were uncovered by pulling on the thread of the graphite electrodes.

  • U.S. v. Stolt-Nielsen,  524 F.Supp.2d 609 (E.D. Pa. 2007)

Well, of course, we didn’t win them all.  This case involved the only attempt by the Antitrust Division to revoke the conditional leniency granted to a company and its executives. After a long battle, Stolt-Nielsen was indicted but the District Court granted a motion to dismiss the indictment, finding that the government had not carried it burden to show that the defendants had breached their obligations under the conditional leniency letter.

  • U.S v. Norris, 719 F. Supp.2d 557 (E.D. Pa. 2010)

In this case, which grew out of the graphite electrodes investigation, Ian Norris was extradited by the U.K. to face obstruction of justice charges. Under the terms of the extradition order, Norris was not tried on the price-fixing count in the indictment. Norris was convicted and sentenced to 18 months in prison.

*************

One last note. There are too many individuals who had successful careers in the Philadelphia Office to name names, but I’ll make one exception. John J. Hughes was to the Philadelphia Field Office what Vince Lombardi was to the Green Bay Packers. As the long-tenured Chief of the office, countless of us had the good fortune to learn from him how to be a tough but fair prosecutor.  He was a cherished mentor and a role model in all aspects of life.  John’s influence spread even wider after he stepped down as Chief in 1994. He became the trial advisor to countless Division criminal trial staffs over the next decade. I spoke to John this week and he said he’d be happy if I included his email for any old friends that wanted to say hello. j_hughes118@comcast.net.  Thanks for reading.

PS.

When I can gather some information, I’d also like to note the achievements of the other field offices that were closed: Atlanta, Cleveland and Dallas. Who knows, someday someone may be interested in Antitrust Division history and this blog post will pop up.

Filed Under: Blog

A Quick Note On Extradition….

February 10, 2015 by Robert Connolly

In the lysine international cartel case in the late 1990’s, ADM executives were sentenced to prison but their foreign counterparts entered no-jail deals with the Antitrust Division.  In the early days of the international cartel program, foreign cartel members were given no-jail deals in return for their testimony because it seemed they were out of reach of the U.S. legal system. Forward to the present day auto parts cartel investigation where over 50 executives have been charged.   Those foreign defendants who are not fugitives have agreed to serve prison terms. What has changed? Extradition! While the number of actual extraditions is still quite small, the threat of extradition on charges brought by the Antitrust Division looms large. Even if a defendant is in a “safe” country, the roster of governments that will honor an extradition request is growing and could take an unfavorable turn for a foreign fugitive. More countries have criminalized cartel behavior and the Division sometimes includes fraud or obstruction charges in indictments, which increases the risk of extradition.  More significantly, the threat of being detained by Interpol on a Red Notice generally means a fugitive from an Antitrust Division indictment will not by using his frequent flier miles for international travel anymore.

All this is generally well-known, and the Antitrust Division aims to keep it that way. But, last week there was an extradition-related development that illustrates another extradition peril.  A defendant extradited to the United States to face antitrust or related charges will be subject to bail conditions while awaiting trial.  These conditions will likely include travel restrictions, even possibly house arrest.

John Bennett, a Canadian citizen, is the former Chief Executive Officer of Bennett Environmental Inc., a Canadian-based company that treated and disposed of contaminated soil. Bennett was indicted in August 2009 (D.N.J.) for his role participating in a conspiracy to pay kickbacks and commit fraud at the U.S. Environmental Protection Agency designated Superfund site in New Jersey. He was also charged with major fraud against the United States, a count that carries a ten-year maximum prison sentence.  The indictment alleges that Bennett carried out the conspiracy by paying kickbacks to Gordon McDonald, the project manager at the site. The kickbacks were transferred by wire to a co-conspirator’s shell company, lavish cruises for senior officials of the prime contractor, and various entertainment tickets. The indictment charged the conspiracy began at least as early as December 2001 and continued until approximately August 2004.

On October 30, 2014 the Supreme Court of Canada denied Bennett’s application for leave to appeal an extradition order. Bennett then made his arrival in the United States in November.  At  Bennett’s first appearance in November, he was released on bail, but Judge Cathy L. Waldor ordered that he surrender his passport, remain under house arrest and wear a tracking device.  Last week Judge Waldor denied Bennett’s request for a change in his bail status.  Bennett’s trial is not scheduled until November 2015.  And should Bennett’s attorneys feel they need more time to prepare and a continuance is granted, his house arrest will likely continue until the date of the trial. The point is that even if Bennett is ultimately acquitted he will have spent at least one under house arrest–an extensive loss of liberty. If he were an American defendant he would almost certainly remain free until his trial date. But, the risk of flight of a foreign defendant, especially one, who like Bennett, fought extradition, makes travel restrictions a near certainty.  Not every extradited defendant will face house arrest, but at a minimum, the surrender of the passport is highly likely. Of course, things could have been worse for Bennett. He could have spent time in a jail in India while an extradition request was being reviewed– but ultimately denied. Or he could have spent nine months in a prison in Germany while his extradition to the U.S. was reviewed—and ultimately granted.  There are other stories of extradition woes, some of which are not public. As the perils of extradition increases, so too does the leverage of the Antitrust Division to bargain for increasing jail sentences for foreign cartel members.

Thanks for reading.

Filed Under: Blog

Two Japan Cartel Related Items of Interest

February 9, 2015 by Robert Connolly

There were two items of interest last week related to cartels and Japan that I wanted to pass on.

A.    Japanese Executives Sentenced to Prison (suspended) In Japan

The quote below is from a report posted last week by Yoshiya Usami of Lane Powell PC on ABA Antitrust Connect.  Mr. Usami reported:

On February 4, the Tokyo District Court convicted NTN Corporation, a Japanese bearing manufacturer, and two of its former executives for violations of Japan’s Antimonopoly Act in connection with its participation in an alleged cartel to fix prices for the sales of bearings, according to Nikkei Shinbun.

As a result of the verdict, the Court imposed a criminal fine of 400 million yen (approximately 3.4 million USD) on the company. The two former executives, one a former director, were sentenced to 18 months and 12 months respectively. However, both sentences were suspended pending completion of a three-year probationary period.

The Japan Fair Trade Commission raided NTN, as well as other Japanese bearing manufacturers, in July 2011. In June 2012, NTN and the two executives were indicted with their alleged conduct in connection with the cartel.

The company immediately filed an appeal to the Tokyo High Court, according to its press release.

***********************

The case is noteworthy to me because unlike most cartel cases in Japan, it was not handled administratively by the JFTC. The JFTC cannot bring criminal charges, but can make a referral to the Tokyo prosecutor’s office, which they did in this case. While the prison sentences were suspended for the individual executives, it is a positive development for cartel enforcement that the indivuduals (and the company) were criminally charged.  (Prison sentences were very rare for nearly a century under the Sherman Act).

Also, the Chinese National Development and Reform Commission had previously fined NTN, after providing leniency to one cooperating company.  Cartels can be extremely profitable, and it is still probably the case that most cartels go undetected. But, with the cartel-disruptive force of leniency, and the ever-increasing penalties, the cost-benefit calculus should be changing more often in favor of “I think I’ll pass on that meeting in the smoke-filled back room of the .…”

B.   Two Former Japanese Auto Parts Executives Indicted on Sherman Act     and Obstruction Counts

Another item of note is that on February 5, 2015, a grand jury returned a two-count indictment against Hiroyuki Komiya and Hirofumi Nakayama, former executives of Mitsuba Corporation.  One count charges price-fixing, the other obstruction of justice. In one way the indictment is unremarkable. The auto parts investigation has entered the “cleanup” phase during which the Antitrust Division will bring cases against individuals the Division deemed culpable enough to charge and who were not willing to enter into plea agreements acceptable to the Division. What is, or may be, noteworthy is the fact that the former executives were indicted for obstruction of justice in addition to price-fixing.

The reason this caught my eye was the possibility of extradition. There are many Japanese fugitives in various global cartel investigations dating back to at least the late 1990’s. The Antitrust Division has never succeeded in having a Japanese national extradited from Japan to face a Sherman Act (15 U.S.C. Section 1) charge, and I don’t believe it likely that the Japanese government will anytime soon agree to extradite one of its citizens for price-fixing. But might it do so for obstruction? I don’t know; but I note that the Division did succeed in having British national extradited for obstruction of justice in 2010 (after a seven-year extradition battle).

The defendant there, Ian Norris, was charged in a four-count indictment: one count of price-fixing and three counts of obstruction. The U.K. extradited the defendant to face the obstruction charges, but not the price-fixing charge. Price fixing was not a crime in the U.K. (at the time) so the price-fixing charge did not meet the “dual criminality” requirement for extradition under the U.S.-U.K. Mutual Legal Assistance Treaty. (All MLATs contain a similar provision.) But if Japan has the equivalent of the U.S. crime of obstruction of justice in its criminal code, which seems likely, it ought to accede to an extradition request, if one is made.  Whether it actually will do so or whether it will find some basis on which to deny the request, of course, remains to be seen.   But, as the saying goes, “The cover up is worse than the crime,” so a government may be persuaded to agree to extradition for obstruction, even if the defendant will not be extradited to face the price-fixing charge.

In the case of the British executive who was extradited to face obstruction charges, the indictment spelled out in great detail (in three counts) the extent and degree of the obstruction. In the current case against the Japanese executives, the indictment charges obstruction in fairly generic language.   Perhaps this means the obstruction indictment is not a prelude to seeking extradition of the defendants from Japan.  The obstruction charge, however, will make international travel even more perilous for the indicted defendants as the grounds for extradition on obstruction is more universally recognized.

For further background, below are some excerpts from the recent Antitrust Division press release describing the charges.

 On February 5, 2015, two former executives of Mitsuba Corp. were indicted for their participation in a conspiracy to fix prices and rig bids of automotive parts and for obstruction of justice for ordering the destruction of evidence related to the conspiracy. The indictment charged Hiroyuki Komiya and Hirofumi Nakayama with conspiring to fix the prices of various automotive parts, including windshield wiper systems and components, sold in the United States and elsewhere. The defendants were also charged with knowingly and corruptly persuading, and attempting to persuade, employees of Mitsuba to destroy documents and delete electronic data that may contain evidence of antitrust crimes in the United States and elsewhere.

Komiya participated in the conspiracy as Mitsuba Director of Automotive Sales. In 2007, he was promoted to Executive Managing Officer and Vice President of Sales. Nakayama was the Office Manager of Mitsuba’s Nagoya sales office. In 2005, he was promoted to Sales Operating Officer.

Mitsuba had previously been charged with price-fixing and obstruction in the auto parts investigation. On November 6, 2014, Mitsuba pleaded guilty and agreed to pay a $135 million criminal fine for its role in the conspiracy as well as obstruction of justice. The Mitsuba information alleged that “[a]fter becoming aware of the FBI search of Defendant’s co-conspirator’s U.S. offices, Executive A informed certain of his subordinates employed at the U.S. subsidiary of Defendant about the FBI search, and instructed such subordinates, as well as other employees of Defendant, to locate, conceal and destroy documents and electronic files that were likely to contain evidence of antitrust crimes in the United States and elsewhere.” Executive A also destroyed and concealed documents in his possession, custody and control in the Eastern District of Michigan that were likely to contain evidence of antitrust crimes in the United States and elsewhere.

I’d be interesting in comments from others about how/whether cartel enforcement is ramping up in Asia.

Thanks for reading.

 

Filed Under: Blog Tagged With: antitrust, cartel, Japan

Why Motorola Mobility was a Good Decision for Global Cartel Enforcement

February 6, 2015 by Robert Connolly

Back in September I wrote an article for Competition Policy International (CPI) on the FTAIA and the now vacated Motorola Mobility I decision.  That article can be read here.  I was honored to have that article quoted at length by Judge Posner in the subsequent decision: Motorola Mobility v. AU Optronics Corp, 2015 WL 137907 (7th Cir., decided Nov 26, 2015, amended January 12, 2015). In this decision, the Seventh Circuit held that purchases made by Motorola Mobility’s foreign subsidiaries of LCD panels, which the subsidiary then incorporated into products sold to the parent for sale in the U.S., did not give rise to a damage claim under the FTAIA. The Court found that the cartel victims were Motorola Mobility’s foreign subsidiaries. The key fact was Motorola Mobility’s claim that it purchased more than $5 billion worth of LCD panels from cartel members. The Court responded: “That’s a critical misstatement. All but 1 percent of the purchases were made by Motorola’s foreign subsidiaries.”

Since there is little doubt that the defendants did fix prices, the dismissal of 99% of Motorola’s claims seemed like a windfall for the cartelists, and a decision that could lead to under deterrence of global cartel enforcement. Motorola Mobility has expressed its intent to seek review in the United States Supreme Court. Because of the ambiguity of the FTAIA and the myriad fact patterns that can arise, policy consideration will play a large role in ultimately deciding the scope of the FTAIA. I thought Motorola Mobility was rightly decided and that the decision is actually pro-cartel enforcement. I explained why I thought that was so in a recent article CPI published as part of an “Motorola Mobility Redux” issue. My paper is titled: “Why the Motorola Mobility Decision Was Good For Cartel Enforcement and Deterrence” can be found here without charge.  (There are other excellent articles in the CPI issue but they require a subscription to view.). Below are excerpts of my thoughts on why I thought the Motorola Mobility decision was good for cartel enforcement.

The initial Seventh Circuit Motorola Mobility, holding that the conduct in question did not “have a direct, substantial and reasonably foreseeable effect” on U.S. commerce, could have seriously jeopardized the Antitrust Division’s international cartel enforcement efforts. Another possible ruling would have allowed Motorola Mobility to seek damages in U.S. courts for purchases made overseas by a foreign subsidiary, but that decision could have created resentment of foreign governments, including those that filed amicus briefs, for having their companies taken into U.S. court to face treble damage actions for sales made overseas. The actual decision to hold only that Motorola Mobility’s claim did not meet the FTAIA’s “gives rise to” requirement was a wise compromise from a policy perspective.

The basic premise of my argument is that international governmental prosecutions are the essential component of global cartel enforcement. Governmental cartel enforcement relies to a great degree on cooperation between U.S and global enforcement agencies.  This cooperation takes many forms, both seen (coordinated dawn raids, MLAT treaties, extradition) and unseen (sharing of information). In this context the amicus briefs filed by foreign governments in the Motorola Mobility case were not to be taken lightly. The foreign governments did not object the Antitrust Division’s prosecution of LCD cartel members. In fact, many foreign governments cooperated in that investigation and also imposed their own penalties. But, the amicus briefs expressed concern that their native businesses could be hauled into U.S. court to face treble damage actions for sales that were not made in the United States. In Motorola Mobility, the Seventh Circuit ruled that the LCD cartel had a “direct, substantial and reasonably foreseeable effect” on U.S. commerce; a decision the Antitrust Division sought to support its cartel program. But the Court also held that if a foreign subsidiary of an American company makes purchases in a foreign country, that country is the place for the purchaser to seek its remedy; a decision foreign governments sought to protect the effectiveness of their own competition regimes.   [Read more…]

Filed Under: Blog Tagged With: Global Cartel Enforcement, Motorola Mobility

CCI fines Port Owner’s Association and Individuals for Price Fixing

February 2, 2015 by Robert Connolly

Today’s guest post is from Avinash Amarnath.

India Update 2015 Vol. 2

Trade associations continue to be the flavor of the day in the cartel space in India.

On 21 January 2015, the Competition Commission of India (CCI) imposed a penalty on the Dumper Owner’s Association (DOA), a trade association of dumper and hywa [unloading] machinery providers for intra-port transportation of cargo at Paradip Port and its individual officers for controlling the supply of dumpers and hywas at Paradip Port and fixing supply prices. The trade association was fined 8% of its average turnover (for the last 3 years) while the individual officers were fined 5% of their average income (for the last 3 years).

The complaint was brought by Swastik Stevedores Private Limited (the Informant), a company engaged in the business of stevedoring and intra-port transportation of cargo alleging that the DOA, in connivance with the Paradip Port Trust (PPT), the government authority managing Paradip Port had been refusing to provide dumpers and hywas to it.

In particular, the CCI found that:

  1. The DOA had been entrusted with the authority to issue gate passes for dumpers and hywas at Paradip Port by the PPT which gave it a unique advantage in controlling supply at the port as no machinery could enter the port without a gate pass. Further, the members of the DOA owned a substantial number of the dumpers used at Paradip Port. The DOA used this control over the supply of dumpers and hywas to refuse supply to the Informant thereby limiting output through collective action in violation of the Competition Act, 2002 (Competition Act); and
  2. The DOA collectively fixed the rates to be charged for provision of dumpers and hywas. The members       were forced to abide by such rates and were not allowed to individually negotiate rates. This resulted in determination of sale prices through collective action in violation of the Competition Act.

The PPT was exonerated, as there was no evidence of any collusive agreement between DOA and PPT.

Interestingly, the Director General (DG), the investigative wing of the CCI, during its investigation had found that the DOA had collectively fixed rates after negotiations with the Paradip Port Stevedores Association (PPSA), an association of stevedores and had concluded that both bodies were liable for price-fixing despite PPSA not being a party to the original complaint. PPSA had raised a preliminary argument that the DG had no jurisdiction to investigate it as it was not a party to the original complaint and accordingly, no investigation had been ordered against it by the CCI. The CCI dismissed this argument by observing that the DG was well within its right to examine the conduct of any entity that is related to the alleged anti-competitive conduct. However, the CCI absolved the PPSA of liability on the ground that the members of the PPSA were consumers of the DOA and such negotiations between consumers and suppliers cannot be construed to be price-fixing.

Another interesting trend to note is the increasing propensity of the CCI to impose penalties on the individual officers of the company/trade association in cartel matters. This is the 8th cartel case in the last year or so where individual officers have been penalized. 

The full decision of the CCI can be accessed here.

Avinash Amarnath can be reached at avinash.aba@gmail.com.  

Filed Under: Blog

Brief Summary of “Obama Administration Antitrust Policy: A Report Card” Program

January 30, 2015 by Robert Connolly

On January 29, 2015 I attended a program hosted by the Heritage Foundation: Obama Administration Antitrust Policy: A Report Card. The program was free and held in the Allison Auditorium. The program had three panels that focused on 1) the FTC; 2) the DOJ, and 3) Antitrust Abroad.   The panels were outstanding and included speakers who were either current or former senior members of the FTC or the Antitrust Division.

The consensus of the speakers was that it is too early to give an overall Antitrust grade to the Obama administration. It can take years to conduct a proper retrospective of how decisions and priorities have played out. Overall, however, there were a number of “high marks” or “good job” given by each of the panels. The DOJ, however was given one failing grade for (my words) “Plays Well With Others.”  Typically when a new administration takes over, new management speaks well of their predecessors, even though they may have a different approach in some areas. This happened with the Bush to Obama transition at the FTC. It did not at the DOJ. Several panelists noted Obama administration DOJ officials were uncharacteristically critical of their immediate predecessors with remarks such as the “antitrust is open for business”[1] and comments made when, in May 2009, the new administration withdrew the September 2008 Section 2 report on monopolization.

The DOJ panel was of particular interest to me.  In my 33 years at the Antitrust Division I worked for both Democratic and Republican Administrations. The panel was moderated by Hill Wellford and the speakers were: The Honorable Douglas Ginsburg, James Rill, J. Mark Gidley, and Thomas Barnett. I had worked under all of them when each was either Assistant Attorney General or Acting Assistant Attorney General at the Division.

The program will be available both in video and audio but these are some of my impressions of the remarks relating to cartel enforcement. Overall, there was a consensus that there had been a high degree of continuity in the criminal cartel program characterized by ever-increasing fines and jail sentences fueled by a focus on international cartels.  Regardless of administration, the focus on criminal antitrust enforcement has been high. For example the panel praised the Division’s Corporate Leniency program, which was revised in 1993 under Anne Bingaman.   Under Hew Pate the Antitrust Criminal Penalty Enhancement and Reform Act (“ACPERA”), expanded leniency to private damage suits and also increased the maximum Sherman Act fine to $100 million and the top jail sentence to 10 years. The panel also noted that the increased level of cooperation with foreign competition authorities has been a bipartisan effort across all recent administrations. This has led to the very successful export of leniency programs and the global view that “cartels are the supreme evil of antitrust.”

The panel had a caution on leniency programs; while hugely important it is equally important that enforcers be vigilant to grant leniency only to hard-core cartel conduct. It was noted that a leniency applicant may have incentive to take a grey area such as information exchange and puff it up to a price-fixing conspiracy. It is possible for a company to use “leniency” as a weapon; get a free pass for itself an its employees, while its competitors get hammered. It was noted, however, that the Division has rejected leniency applications when the applicant hasn’t “confessed a crime.”  There have also been occasions where the Division granted leniency, but did not follow-up with any prosecutions because the evidence was weak. I would add my observation that even the Antitrust Division leniency applicant isn’t quite a free pass.

The DOJ panel covered topics other than cartels, as did the FTC and Antitrust Abroad panels.  The keynote speech by William Kovacic was informative and entertaining.  The program should be online shortly.

 

[1]   While not cited at the program, this speech may be one example that panelists alluded to. See Sharis Pozen, Acting Assistant Attorney General, Antitrust Division, USDOJ, Remarks Before the Brookings Institute, April 23, 2012. http://www.justice.gov/atr/public/speeches/282515.pdf

Filed Under: Blog

LIBOR Guest Post from Richard Wolfram, Esq.

January 29, 2015 by Robert Connolly

I came across a very informative post by Richard Wolfram, Esq. about antitrust standing the LIBOR civil damages litigation.  I thought it would be of interest to Cartel Capers readers, in case you haven’t seen it elsewhere.  Mr. Wolfram kindly agreed to let me repost this.

********************************************
In re LIBOR: ‘More Light, Please!’—Questions and Observations As the Decision Dismissing Antitrust Claims for Lack of Antitrust Injury Now Faces Appellate Review
Posted: 28 Jan 2015 10:01 AM PST
by Richard Wolfram, Esq.

(An in-depth article on In re LIBOR and antitrust injury is available here under this title. The following is a preview of my article).

(N.B.: In a coincidence of timing, on Jan. 28, 2015, the date of this posting and publication of the linked article, Judge Lorna Schofield of the federal district court for the Southern District of New York, in a case alleging a conspiracy to manipulate the benchmark rates in the $5.3 trillion/day foreign exchange market, denied the defendants’ motions to dismiss and expressly rejected the test used by the court in In re LIBOR for determining antitrust injury, discussed below. In re Foreign Exchange Benchmark Rates Antitrust Litigation (S.D.N.Y. 1/28/15).)

A key ruling by a New York federal district court almost two years ago, in In re LIBOR-Based Financial Instruments Antitrust Litigation, can now finally proceed on appeal, and the implications are significant both in the law and for a number of financial markets dependent on benchmark mechanisms.

The district court ruled in March 2013 that alleged collusion by the defendant banks in setting a global interest rate benchmark—the London Interbank Offered Rate, or LIBOR—may have violated antitrust law but did not cause antitrust injury; it therefore dismissed antitrust claims filed by various investors, who claimed injury from the alleged concerted suppression of LIBOR, on the grounds that they lacked standing.

On January 21, 2015, in a lightning-fast decision issued barely six weeks after oral argument, the Supreme Court removed procedural roadblocks delaying prompt appeal. The district court’s decision, so long on the vine (before appeal) that it appeared to be taken as accepted wisdom in some quarters, will now be put to the test and is already attracting heightened, critical attention.

The article examines the district court’s antitrust ruling with a view to the upcoming appeal. Specifically, it explains the U.S. doctrine of private antitrust injury—“injury of the type the antitrust laws were intended to prevent and that flows from that which makes defendants’ acts unlawful”—an elusive and notoriously difficult principle to pinpoint and correctly apply (Part II); sets forth the facts of the case (III) and the court’s rationale (IV); and dissects the court’s reasoning (V).

The district court’s rationale rests on two main findings: first, that the LIBOR-setting process is collaborative, not competitive, so any collusion by the banks in setting the rate did not displace competition, and any resulting harm therefore cannot result from a suppression of competition—hence, there was no antitrust injury; and second, that the injury alleged by the plaintiffs could have occurred even in the absence of the alleged collusion, that is, in normal competitive conditions—hence, the plaintiffs may have been injured but it was not antitrust injury.

The analysis of the first leg of the rationale focuses on the upstream interbank lending market, where each bank was expected to submit its daily estimated interbank borrowing costs, independently, to the British Banking Association (BBA), which then averaged them for the daily LIBOR fix; and on the downstream markets for the sale by the defendant banks of various financial instruments indexed to LIBOR. The court’s conclusion that the banks did not compete in LIBOR rate-setting in the interbank lending market, as a predicate for its conclusion that any injury resulting from the alleged collusion was not antitrust injury, invites scrutiny on at least three fronts:

  • First—the plaintiffs alleged incentives on the part of the banks to compete in the interbank lending market, even if the LIBOR-setting process itself is collaborative; there was not simply a unilateral incentive on the part of each bank to understate its borrowing costs, to reflect a picture of stronger financial health, as noted by the court, but also an interplay of this incentive with the desire on the part of each bank not to substantially overstate or understate its estimated borrowing costs vis à vis those of the other banks contributing their data to the LIBOR fix, thereby prompting their alleged collusion;
  • Second—the required independent submission by the banks to the BBA of their daily estimated interbank lending costs, on which they instead allegedly colluded, resembles the ‘messenger model’ in antitrust, and the similar structural safeguards in each of these two mechanisms against improper information exchange reflects the competitive interrelationship of the participants; and
  • Third—LIBOR-setting resembles standard setting in that both are collaborative information-gathering processes, but with competitive effects; as the law recognizes the antitrust implications of abuse of standard setting, so it should recognize that LIBOR-setting, conducted by banks which compete with each other at least in the downstream markets, if not also in the upstream interbank lending market, may also have competitive effects and cause antitrust injury.

As for the downstream markets for the sale of LIBOR-indexed financial instruments to the plaintiff investors, in which the defendants clearly competed, the Supreme Court’s teaching in Brunswick v. Pueblo Bowl-O-Mat on antitrust injury instructs that the “injury should reflect the anticompetitive effect either of the violation or of the anticompetitive acts made possible by the violation.” If the “violation” is the alleged collusion on LIBOR-setting by the banks, then the “anticompetitive acts made possible by the violation” are the defendants’ pricing of the financial instruments where the plaintiffs allegedly paid more or received less than they would have in a market free from the alleged collusion. Even assuming, for the sake of argument, and per the court, that the LIBOR-setting process was entirely collaborative, so that any collusion among the banks could not displace competition among them at that stage, it is not clear how the suppression of downstream competition does not constitute antitrust injury (as the anticompetitive acts made possible by violation).

The second leg of the rationale—that whatever harm the plaintiffs may have suffered is not antitrust injury because it could have occurred even in the absence of the alleged collusion, that is, in normal competitive conditions—similarly invites scrutiny. Although the district court appears to ground this reasoning on well-known Supreme Court precedent on antitrust injury, it appears to have misconstrued or at least misapplied it to the facts in LIBOR. Instead, as the article explains, the court appears to have fallen into the ‘Trap of the Irrelevant Hypothetical’—a term coined by one commentator to describe “the fallacious proposition that any time one can construct a counterfactual hypothetical in which (a) the facts are changed such that there is no antitrust violation, yet (b) the plaintiff still suffers damage similar to the injury it actually suffered as a result of the violation, there is no antitrust injury.” With respect to LIBOR, this translates to saying that if the alleged collusion is assumed away, the conduct that would be left—the independent submission of each bank’s daily estimated interbank borrowing costs possibly resulting in the same kind of harm to plaintiffs—would not cause antitrust injury; indeed, it would not even violate the antitrust laws. Accordingly, the ‘irrelevant hypothetical’, taken to its logical extension, would eviscerate private antitrust litigation and the court’s test therefore does not work: by proving too much, it proves nothing.

Although the doctrine of antitrust injury is somewhat ‘plastic’ and does not lend itself to easy or simple formulation, the proper question here, as the Supreme Court has instructed, is instead whether the conduct of which the plaintiffs complain enhances or reduces competition and whether, applied to the facts in LIBOR, a different result obtains. In sum, it does not appear that the district court correctly applied Supreme Court precedent on antitrust injury or that the second leg of its rationale supports its conclusion that the banks’ alleged collusion could not cause antitrust injury. But the district court is not alone: a number of other courts have also stumbled over the doctrine, with some employing the exact same reasoning as the district court in LIBOR. Here, the article spotlights judicial confusion of antitrust injury with either antitrust causation or harm to competition, with illustrations from other decisions.

Ultimately, the issues under discussion resolve to whether the district court in LIBOR correctly dismissed the antitrust claims for failure by the plaintiffs to plausibly allege antitrust injury. The dismissal, which appears to assume facts in question going to the issue of antitrust injury, of course precludes the plaintiffs even from obtaining discovery on this very question, let alone other substantive elements of their claims, yet the plaintiffs appear to have crossed the ‘plausibility’ pleading threshold of Bell Atlantic Corp. v. Twombly. The article suggests that the court’s dismissal of the antitrust claims calls for a critical re-examination of the two principal legs of the rationale and, ultimately, reversal by the Second Circuit.

About Richard Wolfram

Richard Wolfram is an independent lawyer based in New York City who focuses on antitrust counseling and litigation on behalf of corporations, professional organizations and public advocacy entities.

• Leave a comment on In re LIBOR: ‘More Light, Please!’—Questions and Observations As the Decision Dismissing Antitrust Claims for Lack of Antitrust Injury Now Faces Appellate Review

Filed Under: Blog

  • « Previous Page
  • 1
  • …
  • 26
  • 27
  • 28
  • 29
  • 30
  • …
  • 35
  • Next Page »

Search this site

The US Supreme Court has called cartels "the supreme evil of antitrust." Price fixing and bid rigging may not be all that evil as far as supreme evils go, but an individual can get 10 years in jail and corporations can be fined hundreds of millions of dollars. This blog will provide news, insight and analysis of the world of cartels based on the many years my colleagues and I have as former feds with the Antitrust Division, USDOJ.

© Copyright 2014 Cartel Capers · All Rights Reserved