Cartel Capers

A blog about cartels, competition and compliance

100 Blawg Honoree
  • Home
  • Bob Connolly
    • Contact
  • Antitrust Resources
  • Enforcement Agencies
  • Whistleblower Blog

CCI fines Port Owner’s Association and Individuals for Price Fixing

February 2, 2015 by Robert Connolly

Today’s guest post is from Avinash Amarnath.

India Update 2015 Vol. 2

Trade associations continue to be the flavor of the day in the cartel space in India.

On 21 January 2015, the Competition Commission of India (CCI) imposed a penalty on the Dumper Owner’s Association (DOA), a trade association of dumper and hywa [unloading] machinery providers for intra-port transportation of cargo at Paradip Port and its individual officers for controlling the supply of dumpers and hywas at Paradip Port and fixing supply prices. The trade association was fined 8% of its average turnover (for the last 3 years) while the individual officers were fined 5% of their average income (for the last 3 years).

The complaint was brought by Swastik Stevedores Private Limited (the Informant), a company engaged in the business of stevedoring and intra-port transportation of cargo alleging that the DOA, in connivance with the Paradip Port Trust (PPT), the government authority managing Paradip Port had been refusing to provide dumpers and hywas to it.

In particular, the CCI found that:

  1. The DOA had been entrusted with the authority to issue gate passes for dumpers and hywas at Paradip Port by the PPT which gave it a unique advantage in controlling supply at the port as no machinery could enter the port without a gate pass. Further, the members of the DOA owned a substantial number of the dumpers used at Paradip Port. The DOA used this control over the supply of dumpers and hywas to refuse supply to the Informant thereby limiting output through collective action in violation of the Competition Act, 2002 (Competition Act); and
  2. The DOA collectively fixed the rates to be charged for provision of dumpers and hywas. The members       were forced to abide by such rates and were not allowed to individually negotiate rates. This resulted in determination of sale prices through collective action in violation of the Competition Act.

The PPT was exonerated, as there was no evidence of any collusive agreement between DOA and PPT.

Interestingly, the Director General (DG), the investigative wing of the CCI, during its investigation had found that the DOA had collectively fixed rates after negotiations with the Paradip Port Stevedores Association (PPSA), an association of stevedores and had concluded that both bodies were liable for price-fixing despite PPSA not being a party to the original complaint. PPSA had raised a preliminary argument that the DG had no jurisdiction to investigate it as it was not a party to the original complaint and accordingly, no investigation had been ordered against it by the CCI. The CCI dismissed this argument by observing that the DG was well within its right to examine the conduct of any entity that is related to the alleged anti-competitive conduct. However, the CCI absolved the PPSA of liability on the ground that the members of the PPSA were consumers of the DOA and such negotiations between consumers and suppliers cannot be construed to be price-fixing.

Another interesting trend to note is the increasing propensity of the CCI to impose penalties on the individual officers of the company/trade association in cartel matters. This is the 8th cartel case in the last year or so where individual officers have been penalized. 

The full decision of the CCI can be accessed here.

Avinash Amarnath can be reached at [email protected].  

Filed Under: Blog

Brief Summary of “Obama Administration Antitrust Policy: A Report Card” Program

January 30, 2015 by Robert Connolly

On January 29, 2015 I attended a program hosted by the Heritage Foundation: Obama Administration Antitrust Policy: A Report Card. The program was free and held in the Allison Auditorium. The program had three panels that focused on 1) the FTC; 2) the DOJ, and 3) Antitrust Abroad.   The panels were outstanding and included speakers who were either current or former senior members of the FTC or the Antitrust Division.

The consensus of the speakers was that it is too early to give an overall Antitrust grade to the Obama administration. It can take years to conduct a proper retrospective of how decisions and priorities have played out. Overall, however, there were a number of “high marks” or “good job” given by each of the panels. The DOJ, however was given one failing grade for (my words) “Plays Well With Others.”  Typically when a new administration takes over, new management speaks well of their predecessors, even though they may have a different approach in some areas. This happened with the Bush to Obama transition at the FTC. It did not at the DOJ. Several panelists noted Obama administration DOJ officials were uncharacteristically critical of their immediate predecessors with remarks such as the “antitrust is open for business”[1] and comments made when, in May 2009, the new administration withdrew the September 2008 Section 2 report on monopolization.

The DOJ panel was of particular interest to me.  In my 33 years at the Antitrust Division I worked for both Democratic and Republican Administrations. The panel was moderated by Hill Wellford and the speakers were: The Honorable Douglas Ginsburg, James Rill, J. Mark Gidley, and Thomas Barnett. I had worked under all of them when each was either Assistant Attorney General or Acting Assistant Attorney General at the Division.

The program will be available both in video and audio but these are some of my impressions of the remarks relating to cartel enforcement. Overall, there was a consensus that there had been a high degree of continuity in the criminal cartel program characterized by ever-increasing fines and jail sentences fueled by a focus on international cartels.  Regardless of administration, the focus on criminal antitrust enforcement has been high. For example the panel praised the Division’s Corporate Leniency program, which was revised in 1993 under Anne Bingaman.   Under Hew Pate the Antitrust Criminal Penalty Enhancement and Reform Act (“ACPERA”), expanded leniency to private damage suits and also increased the maximum Sherman Act fine to $100 million and the top jail sentence to 10 years. The panel also noted that the increased level of cooperation with foreign competition authorities has been a bipartisan effort across all recent administrations. This has led to the very successful export of leniency programs and the global view that “cartels are the supreme evil of antitrust.”

The panel had a caution on leniency programs; while hugely important it is equally important that enforcers be vigilant to grant leniency only to hard-core cartel conduct. It was noted that a leniency applicant may have incentive to take a grey area such as information exchange and puff it up to a price-fixing conspiracy. It is possible for a company to use “leniency” as a weapon; get a free pass for itself an its employees, while its competitors get hammered. It was noted, however, that the Division has rejected leniency applications when the applicant hasn’t “confessed a crime.”  There have also been occasions where the Division granted leniency, but did not follow-up with any prosecutions because the evidence was weak. I would add my observation that even the Antitrust Division leniency applicant isn’t quite a free pass.

The DOJ panel covered topics other than cartels, as did the FTC and Antitrust Abroad panels.  The keynote speech by William Kovacic was informative and entertaining.  The program should be online shortly.

 

[1]   While not cited at the program, this speech may be one example that panelists alluded to. See Sharis Pozen, Acting Assistant Attorney General, Antitrust Division, USDOJ, Remarks Before the Brookings Institute, April 23, 2012. http://www.justice.gov/atr/public/speeches/282515.pdf

Filed Under: Blog

A Report Card: “Obama Administration Antitrust Policy

January 30, 2015 by B Gee

Brief Summary of “Obama Administration Antitrust Policy: A Report Card” Program

January 30, 2015 by Robert Connolly Leave a Comment

On January 29, 2015 I attended a program hosted by the Heritage Foundation: Obama Administration Antitrust Policy: A Report Card. The program was free and held in the Allison Auditorium. The program had three panels that focused on 1) the FTC; 2) the DOJ, and 3) Antitrust Abroad.   The panels were outstanding and included speakers who were either current or former senior members of the FTC or the Antitrust Division.

The consensus of the speakers was that it is too early to give an overall Antitrust grade to the Obama administration. It can take years to conduct a proper retrospective of how decisions and priorities have played out. Overall, however, there were a number of “high marks” or “good job” given by each of the panels. The DOJ, however was given one failing grade for (my words) “Plays Well With Others.”  Typically when a new administration takes over, new management speaks well of their predecessors, even though they may have a different approach in some areas. This happened with the Bush to Obama transition at the FTC. It did not at the DOJ. Several panelists noted Obama administration DOJ officials were uncharacteristically critical of their immediate predecessors with remarks such as the “antitrust is open for business”[1] and comments made when, in May 2009, the new administration withdrew the September 2008 Section 2 report on monopolization.

Filed Under: Blog

LIBOR Guest Post from Richard Wolfram, Esq.

January 29, 2015 by Robert Connolly

I came across a very informative post by Richard Wolfram, Esq. about antitrust standing the LIBOR civil damages litigation.  I thought it would be of interest to Cartel Capers readers, in case you haven’t seen it elsewhere.  Mr. Wolfram kindly agreed to let me repost this.

********************************************
In re LIBOR: ‘More Light, Please!’—Questions and Observations As the Decision Dismissing Antitrust Claims for Lack of Antitrust Injury Now Faces Appellate Review
Posted: 28 Jan 2015 10:01 AM PST
by Richard Wolfram, Esq.

(An in-depth article on In re LIBOR and antitrust injury is available here under this title. The following is a preview of my article).

(N.B.: In a coincidence of timing, on Jan. 28, 2015, the date of this posting and publication of the linked article, Judge Lorna Schofield of the federal district court for the Southern District of New York, in a case alleging a conspiracy to manipulate the benchmark rates in the $5.3 trillion/day foreign exchange market, denied the defendants’ motions to dismiss and expressly rejected the test used by the court in In re LIBOR for determining antitrust injury, discussed below. In re Foreign Exchange Benchmark Rates Antitrust Litigation (S.D.N.Y. 1/28/15).)

A key ruling by a New York federal district court almost two years ago, in In re LIBOR-Based Financial Instruments Antitrust Litigation, can now finally proceed on appeal, and the implications are significant both in the law and for a number of financial markets dependent on benchmark mechanisms.

The district court ruled in March 2013 that alleged collusion by the defendant banks in setting a global interest rate benchmark—the London Interbank Offered Rate, or LIBOR—may have violated antitrust law but did not cause antitrust injury; it therefore dismissed antitrust claims filed by various investors, who claimed injury from the alleged concerted suppression of LIBOR, on the grounds that they lacked standing.

On January 21, 2015, in a lightning-fast decision issued barely six weeks after oral argument, the Supreme Court removed procedural roadblocks delaying prompt appeal. The district court’s decision, so long on the vine (before appeal) that it appeared to be taken as accepted wisdom in some quarters, will now be put to the test and is already attracting heightened, critical attention.

The article examines the district court’s antitrust ruling with a view to the upcoming appeal. Specifically, it explains the U.S. doctrine of private antitrust injury—“injury of the type the antitrust laws were intended to prevent and that flows from that which makes defendants’ acts unlawful”—an elusive and notoriously difficult principle to pinpoint and correctly apply (Part II); sets forth the facts of the case (III) and the court’s rationale (IV); and dissects the court’s reasoning (V).

The district court’s rationale rests on two main findings: first, that the LIBOR-setting process is collaborative, not competitive, so any collusion by the banks in setting the rate did not displace competition, and any resulting harm therefore cannot result from a suppression of competition—hence, there was no antitrust injury; and second, that the injury alleged by the plaintiffs could have occurred even in the absence of the alleged collusion, that is, in normal competitive conditions—hence, the plaintiffs may have been injured but it was not antitrust injury.

The analysis of the first leg of the rationale focuses on the upstream interbank lending market, where each bank was expected to submit its daily estimated interbank borrowing costs, independently, to the British Banking Association (BBA), which then averaged them for the daily LIBOR fix; and on the downstream markets for the sale by the defendant banks of various financial instruments indexed to LIBOR. The court’s conclusion that the banks did not compete in LIBOR rate-setting in the interbank lending market, as a predicate for its conclusion that any injury resulting from the alleged collusion was not antitrust injury, invites scrutiny on at least three fronts:

  • First—the plaintiffs alleged incentives on the part of the banks to compete in the interbank lending market, even if the LIBOR-setting process itself is collaborative; there was not simply a unilateral incentive on the part of each bank to understate its borrowing costs, to reflect a picture of stronger financial health, as noted by the court, but also an interplay of this incentive with the desire on the part of each bank not to substantially overstate or understate its estimated borrowing costs vis à vis those of the other banks contributing their data to the LIBOR fix, thereby prompting their alleged collusion;
  • Second—the required independent submission by the banks to the BBA of their daily estimated interbank lending costs, on which they instead allegedly colluded, resembles the ‘messenger model’ in antitrust, and the similar structural safeguards in each of these two mechanisms against improper information exchange reflects the competitive interrelationship of the participants; and
  • Third—LIBOR-setting resembles standard setting in that both are collaborative information-gathering processes, but with competitive effects; as the law recognizes the antitrust implications of abuse of standard setting, so it should recognize that LIBOR-setting, conducted by banks which compete with each other at least in the downstream markets, if not also in the upstream interbank lending market, may also have competitive effects and cause antitrust injury.

As for the downstream markets for the sale of LIBOR-indexed financial instruments to the plaintiff investors, in which the defendants clearly competed, the Supreme Court’s teaching in Brunswick v. Pueblo Bowl-O-Mat on antitrust injury instructs that the “injury should reflect the anticompetitive effect either of the violation or of the anticompetitive acts made possible by the violation.” If the “violation” is the alleged collusion on LIBOR-setting by the banks, then the “anticompetitive acts made possible by the violation” are the defendants’ pricing of the financial instruments where the plaintiffs allegedly paid more or received less than they would have in a market free from the alleged collusion. Even assuming, for the sake of argument, and per the court, that the LIBOR-setting process was entirely collaborative, so that any collusion among the banks could not displace competition among them at that stage, it is not clear how the suppression of downstream competition does not constitute antitrust injury (as the anticompetitive acts made possible by violation).

The second leg of the rationale—that whatever harm the plaintiffs may have suffered is not antitrust injury because it could have occurred even in the absence of the alleged collusion, that is, in normal competitive conditions—similarly invites scrutiny. Although the district court appears to ground this reasoning on well-known Supreme Court precedent on antitrust injury, it appears to have misconstrued or at least misapplied it to the facts in LIBOR. Instead, as the article explains, the court appears to have fallen into the ‘Trap of the Irrelevant Hypothetical’—a term coined by one commentator to describe “the fallacious proposition that any time one can construct a counterfactual hypothetical in which (a) the facts are changed such that there is no antitrust violation, yet (b) the plaintiff still suffers damage similar to the injury it actually suffered as a result of the violation, there is no antitrust injury.” With respect to LIBOR, this translates to saying that if the alleged collusion is assumed away, the conduct that would be left—the independent submission of each bank’s daily estimated interbank borrowing costs possibly resulting in the same kind of harm to plaintiffs—would not cause antitrust injury; indeed, it would not even violate the antitrust laws. Accordingly, the ‘irrelevant hypothetical’, taken to its logical extension, would eviscerate private antitrust litigation and the court’s test therefore does not work: by proving too much, it proves nothing.

Although the doctrine of antitrust injury is somewhat ‘plastic’ and does not lend itself to easy or simple formulation, the proper question here, as the Supreme Court has instructed, is instead whether the conduct of which the plaintiffs complain enhances or reduces competition and whether, applied to the facts in LIBOR, a different result obtains. In sum, it does not appear that the district court correctly applied Supreme Court precedent on antitrust injury or that the second leg of its rationale supports its conclusion that the banks’ alleged collusion could not cause antitrust injury. But the district court is not alone: a number of other courts have also stumbled over the doctrine, with some employing the exact same reasoning as the district court in LIBOR. Here, the article spotlights judicial confusion of antitrust injury with either antitrust causation or harm to competition, with illustrations from other decisions.

Ultimately, the issues under discussion resolve to whether the district court in LIBOR correctly dismissed the antitrust claims for failure by the plaintiffs to plausibly allege antitrust injury. The dismissal, which appears to assume facts in question going to the issue of antitrust injury, of course precludes the plaintiffs even from obtaining discovery on this very question, let alone other substantive elements of their claims, yet the plaintiffs appear to have crossed the ‘plausibility’ pleading threshold of Bell Atlantic Corp. v. Twombly. The article suggests that the court’s dismissal of the antitrust claims calls for a critical re-examination of the two principal legs of the rationale and, ultimately, reversal by the Second Circuit.

About Richard Wolfram

Richard Wolfram is an independent lawyer based in New York City who focuses on antitrust counseling and litigation on behalf of corporations, professional organizations and public advocacy entities.

• Leave a comment on In re LIBOR: ‘More Light, Please!’—Questions and Observations As the Decision Dismissing Antitrust Claims for Lack of Antitrust Injury Now Faces Appellate Review

Filed Under: Blog

Antitrust Division Announces FY 2014 Criminal Fine Total

January 23, 2015 by Robert Connolly

The Antitrust Division just issued a press release announcing that it collected $1.861 billion in criminal fines for its fiscal year that ended Sept. 30, 2014.  The highlights are that four companies paid fines in excess of $100 million (the Sherman Act maximum), led by the $425 million fine against Bridgestone Corp.   The full press release is below:

***************************************************

FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE AT
THURSDAY, JANUARY 22, 2015 (202) 514-2007
WWW.JUSTICE.GOV TTY (866) 544-5309

ANTITRUST DIVISION ANNOUNCES FISCAL YEAR TOTAL
IN CRIMINAL FINES COLLECTED

The Department of Justice collected $1.861 billion in criminal fines and penalties resulting from Antitrust Division prosecutions in the fiscal year that ended on Sept. 30, 2014. Contributing in part to one of the largest yearly collections for the division, five of the companies paid in full penalties that exceeded $100 million, including a $425 million criminal fine levied against Bridgestone Corp., the fourth-largest fine the Antitrust Division has ever obtained. The second-largest fine collected was a $195 million criminal fine levied against Hitachi Automotive Systems Ltd. The three additional companies that paid fines and penalties exceeding $100 million were Mitsubishi Electric Corp. with $190 million, Toyo Tire & Rubber Co. Ltd. with $120 million and JTEKT Corp. with $103.2 million. The collection total also includes penalties of more than $561 million received as a result of the division’s LIBOR investigation, which has been conducted in cooperation with the Justice Department’s Criminal Division. In addition, in the last fiscal year the division obtained jail terms for 21 individual defendants, with an average sentence of 26 months, the third-highest average ever.

“The size of these penalties is an unfortunate reminder of the powerful temptation to cheat the American consumer and profit from collusion,” said Assistant Attorney General Bill Baer for the Antitrust Division. “We remain committed to ensuring that corporations and individuals who collude face serious consequences for their crimes.”

Filed Under: Blog

EU Competition Policy Brief–The Damages Directive

January 21, 2015 by Robert Connolly

Last week Cartel Capers featured a post from James Musgrove and Joshua Chad, What Fresh Hell Is This: The Canadian Cartel Class Action System.  I wanted to follow up that post with an update on collective redress in Europe. On November 26, 2104 the European Parliament adopted certain rules governing actions for damages under national law for infringement of the competition law provisions of the Member States and of the European Union. The “Damages Directive” was published on December 5, 2014 and EU countries need to implement it by December 27, 2016. The aim of the Directive is more efficient enforcement of the EU competition rules by making it easier for victims of antitrust violations to claim compensation. While larger companies already often obtain redress for price-fixing overcharges in Europe, the Directive aims to make recovery a realistic options for smaller companies and consumers.

For more information see the EU Competition Policy Brief—The Damages Directive, January 2015.

Thanks for reading.

Filed Under: Blog

India Update 2015, Volume 1.

January 19, 2015 by Robert Connolly

Today’s post is the first in 2015 from my friend in India, Avinash Amarath.

****************************

I wish all readers of Cartel Capers a very happy and prosperous new year. There are two items to report for the first India post of the New Year.

Film Distributor Trade Association fined for price fixing and collective boycott

In its last reported decisions of 2014, the Competition Commission of India (CCI), in two separate cases, fined the Film Distributors Association of Kerala (a state in India) 5% of its turnover (in each case) for indulging in price fixing and collective boycott respectively. The business chain for films in India broadly comprises producers, distributors and exhibitors (i.e. cinema halls and multiplexes).

In one case based on a complaint from a film exhibitor, the CCI found that the association had imposed a revenue sharing pattern on all its members thereby not allowing film exhibitors to negotiate independently with the individual distributors of the association. The association had enforced its decision by stopping screening of all movies in cinema halls that did not accept its terms and by imposing fines on members who did not implement its terms.

In the other case based on a complaint from a member of the association itself, the CCI found that the association had issued a circular calling for collective boycott of two film producers. Again, the association had enforced its decision by imposing monetary penalties and suspending members who violated its decision.

Apart from the fine on the association, the CCI also decided to impose fines on the individual office bearers of the association at the time of the anti-competitive conduct. Separately, the CCI has also decided to initiate proceedings against these office bearers for non-cooperation in the investigation process of the Director General (DG).

An interesting takeaway from these decisions is that the CCI, while deciding on the fine to be imposed on the association, took into account the association’s new office bearers’ cooperation and compliance with the DG’s investigation as a mitigating factor.

The full decisions of the CCI can be found at the following links:

http://www.cci.gov.in/May2011/OrderOfCommission/27/622012.pdf

http://www.cci.gov.in/May2011/OrderOfCommission/27/322013.pdf

Banks found to have not colluded[1]

Bob had already covered this item very well last week. So I am going to just add a few more thoughts to what Bob has already covered. The basic principle that parallel behavior by itself cannot constitute evidence of an agreement has now become a well established principle of Indian competition law with both the CCI and the Competition Appellate Tribunal (COMPAT) adopting this baseline principle in several cases. In fact in the Tyres decision, the CCI observed that in oligopolistic markets, a distinction had to be made between parallelism stemming from an anti-competitive cartel agreement and rational conscious parallelism stemming from the interdependence of firms’ actions.

The Tyres decision is available here: http://www.cci.gov.in/May2011/OrderOfCommission/202008.pdf

Avinash can be reached at  [email protected]

[1]  To be more precise, the Order of the CCI stated “There is nothing on record to even prima facie persuade the Commission that the alleged agreement has been arrived at by the Opposite Parties in concert.”   http://www.cci.gov.in/May2011/OrderOfCommission/262/812014.pdf

Filed Under: Blog

What Fresh Hell is This? The Canadian Cartel Class Action System

January 14, 2015 by Robert Connolly

In Canadian Cartel News Volume 6, James Musgrove and Joshua Chad of McMillan LLP discuss the Canadian class action system.

***********************************************

The answer to Miss Parker’s question, for those in the midst of a cartel investigation, is, almost certainly, a follow-on class action claim. In this volume of Cartel Capers we aim to give a rough and ready overview of the class action system for cartel cases in Canada. A book could be written on this subject – some have been – so these are merely the highest of lights.

The first point to note is that what used to be called follow-on class actions (that is, follow-on after a criminal conviction) is now a misnomer. Like in the US, these are now parallel or even precursor class actions. The merest hint of a cartel investigation results in the filing of class action applications.

Canadian class actions are similar to those in the US in many respects. Whether it is auto parts, computer screens or memory chips, most international price fixing cases have their parallel Canadian class actions. As well, domestic cartels – such as in retail gasoline or chocolate – also give rise to specific Canadian class actions. Since most readers will be familiar with the US system, the most effective way to provide quick advice on the Canadian system may be to note some of the differences. In no particular order, the principal differences include the following:

  1. The Supreme Court of Canada recently confirmed[1] that indirect purchaser actions are permitted. This is particularly important in Canada, given that many products only come to Canada indirectly – often as components in end-use products. The Canadian courts are instructed to seek to avoid double recovery – given the fact that these same products may have been the subject of litigation abroad – but how this will be achieved is uncertain.
  2. Certification in Canada is probably, at least right now, somewhat easier than it is in the US. The standard established by the Supreme Court of Canada in Microsoft is:

“the expert methodology must be sufficiently credible or plausible to establish some basis in fact for the commonality requirement. This means that the methodology must offer a realistic prospect of establishing loss on a class-wide basis…. The methodology cannot be purely theoretical or hypothetical, but must be grounded in the facts of the particular case in question. There must be some evidence of the availability of the data to which the methodology is to be applied.”[2]

This appears to be a lower standard than the Hydrogen Peroxide[3] standard in the US, but see below.   [Read more…]

Filed Under: Blog

Seventh Circuit Denies Motorola Mobility’s Petition for En Banc Hearing

January 13, 2015 by Robert Connolly

On January 12, 2015 the Seventh Circuit denied Motorola Mobility’s request for an en banc hearing.  The text of the order is:

On December 17, 2014, plaintiff‐appellant filed a petition for rehearing en banc. All the judges on the original panel have voted to deny the petition, and none of the active judges has requested a vote on the petition for rehearing en banc.*  The petition is therefore DENIED.

* Circuit Judge Joel M. Flaum did not participate in the consideration of this petition for rehearing.

For prior posts on Motorola Mobility LLC v. AU Optronics Corp.  see  https://cartelcapers.com/blog/477/ and  https://cartelcapers.com/blog/seventh-circuit-rules-motorola-mobility/

Filed Under: Blog

Banks Found Not to Have Colluded

January 9, 2015 by Robert Connolly

I have really enjoyed publishing this blog.  One of the downsides is the embarrassment of an occasional typo, a problem with margins or other technical issues, or like yesterday, when I forgot to include a headline.  But, the  headline above is not a typo.  Banks have been found not to have colluded.

In India, the Competition Commission of India (CCI) dismissed allegations that banks had colluded had to control and determine prices in the gold loan business (here).  It is welcome to see the reasoning of the CCI:  “It may be observed that parallel behaviour needs to be substantiated with the additional evidence or the plus factors to bring it into the ambit of prohibited anti-competitive agreements.”  Of course, what does constitute an agreement is an elusive concept debated by plaintiffs and defendants in the United States on a regular basis.  See, A Recap of 2104 Sherman Act Twombly Decisions.  But, it is heartening to see the CCI starting with the baseline that mere parallel conduct is not sufficient to establish an agreement.  A copy of the CCI order can be found here.

India is becoming an important player in the international cartel world. In the first three-quarters of 2014, the CCI had imposed penalties on 169 entities amounting to more than Rs 2,675 crore (here).  ($425 million US by my inexpert conversion of rupees to US dollars at current rate.). 

Thanks for reading.

Filed Under: Blog

  • « Previous Page
  • 1
  • …
  • 28
  • 29
  • 30
  • 31
  • 32
  • …
  • 36
  • Next Page »

Search this site

The US Supreme Court has called cartels "the supreme evil of antitrust." Price fixing and bid rigging may not be all that evil as far as supreme evils go, but an individual can get 10 years in jail and corporations can be fined hundreds of millions of dollars. This blog will provide news, insight and analysis of the world of cartels based on the many years my colleagues and I have as former feds with the Antitrust Division, USDOJ.

© Copyright 2014 Cartel Capers · All Rights Reserved