Cartel Capers

A blog about cartels, competition and compliance

100 Blawg Honoree
  • Home
  • Bob Connolly
    • Contact
  • Antitrust Resources
  • Enforcement Agencies
  • Whistleblower Blog

Noteworthy Comments by Makan Delrahim at the ABA Antitrust Section Conference in Buenos Aires

May 14, 2019 by Robert Connolly

Assistant Attorney General Makan Delrahim gave a talk on Friday, May 10, 2019 at an ABA Antitrust Section of Law conference in Buenos Aires, Argentina. The full remarks can be read here.

Mr. Delrahim made reference to two policy changes that are in the works involving two key Antitrust Division policies : 1) Corporate Leniency; and 2) Credit for Compliance Programs.  This talk did not indicate what changes may be in store, but Mr. Delrahim’s remarks are worth noting (in italics below):

Leniency Policy

The Antitrust Division has several important tools for detecting cartels, but the leniency program has proven to be our most effective tool by far.  Under the Antitrust Division’s Corporate Leniency Policy, the company (and any cooperating employee) that first reports its involvement in illegal activity can qualify for a complete pass from criminal prosecution in exchange for providing comprehensive cooperation to the Antitrust Division during its investigation.

As of now, over 80 jurisdictions across the globe have developed leniency programs, including nine so far in Latin America.  These programs have changed the landscape of antitrust enforcement throughout the Americas.

 One area where we are taking steps to improve is to protect against the imposition of duplicative penalties.  We hope to ensure that each jurisdiction imposes penalties that reflect the specific harm to its own markets and consumers.  One simple way to achieve this goal is for enforcers to have open discussions about our methodologies for calculating fines in specific cases. These dialogues not only may help prevent overlapping fines and decrease unnecessary burdens on parties, but also can ensure that penalties cover the full scope of the harm caused by the cartel.  

Corporate Compliance Programs

One option [to credit robust compliance programs] would involve formally recognizing that even a good corporate citizen with a comprehensive compliance program may nevertheless find itself implicated in a cartel investigation. While we have credited extraordinary prospective commitment to corporate compliance before, we are also considering how to credit robust compliance programs at the charging stage, even when efforts to deter and detect misconduct were not fully successful in this particular instance.

The Antitrust Division long has been home to the ultimate credit for an effective compliance program that detects and allows prompt self-reporting—leniency.  Going forward, however, leniency will no longer be the only benefit.

 Whatever the exact nature of our policy changes, the Division will move away from its previous refrain that leniency is the only potential reward for companies with an effective and robust compliance program.  In line with the Department of Justice and its other components, we can and must do more to reward and incentivize good corporate citizenship.

https://www.justice.gov/opa/speech/assistant-attorney-general-makan-delrahim-delivers-remarks-american-bar-association

Some Thoughts on These Potential Developments

The Criminal Division of the Department of Justice recently released guidelines for the Evaluation of Corporate Compliance Program (April 2019) here.  These guidelines do not cover the Antitrust Division but are still helpful in understanding factors that may result in credit for antitrust compliance programs.

Mr. Delrahim quoted Mexican film director Alejandro Gonzalez Inarrutu who said, “To question your own process is a necessity.  If you don’t question yourself, it’s impossible to improve.”   I encourage the Antitrust Division to question whether sweetening the pot for corporate whistleblowers is the only way to strengthen the Corporate Leniency Policy and increase cartel enforcement.  It’s time for a whistleblower provision to reward individuals, not just companies, who come forward.  Kimberly Justice (Freed Kanner London & Millen) and I have had careers as prosecutors in the Philadelphia Field Office of the Antitrust Division.  We are now in private practice and deal with potential whistleblowers.  We have written two articles that more fully explain how and why a cartel whistleblower statute would work: The Political Stars Align for a Criminal Antitrust Whistleblower statute,  February 8, 2019, Antitrust Law Daily, available at http://business.cch.com/ald/ALD_Criminal-Antitrust-Whistleblower-Statute_20190208.pdf; and It’s a Crime There Isn’t a Criminal Antitrust Whistleblower Statute, Antitrust Law Daily April 5, 2018, available at http://business.cch.com/ald/ALD_Criminal-Antitrust-Whistleblower-Statute_04-05-2018_final_locked.pdf.

Two points I’d like to address here, because I believe they are misunderstood, is that an individual whistleblower program:

1) would enhance, not undermine, the Corporate Leniency Program; and

2) a cartel individual whistleblower statute would also enhance, not undermine, corporate compliance programs.

  1.  Individual Whistleblowing Incentives Will Lead to Increased Corporate Leniency Applications

Whether one believes that leniency applications are down (at least for major international cartels), or whether leniency applications are in line with historical norms, there is no reason that the Corporate Leniency Program should not be improved.  A cartel whistleblower statute will increase, not decrease, the effectiveness of the corporate leniency program.

Type A Leniency

There are no public statistics but anecdotally attorneys suggest that some companies that discover cartel issues are not coming forward with Type A leniency because the costs of cooperation and civil damage suits outweigh the benefits of sitting back and hoping the cartel is never discovered.[1]  The discussion in the corporate board room about what to do with a discovered cartel problem will be quite different if the company has to worry about an individual whistleblower having incentives to report the wrongdoing.  Currently, a company may (and some allegedly have) bet that another cartel member won’t go in for Type A leniency because that company faces the same enormous collateral consequences of exposing the cartel.  An individual whistleblower, of course, faces enormous blowback from being a whistleblower, but a possible financial reward may overcome these disincentives.  In terms of destabilizing cartels and promoting Type A leniency, the wildcard of a possible individual whistleblower certainly moves the cost/benefit analysis of seeking Type A leniency towards self-disclosure.

 Type B Leniency

Individual whistleblowers will also help generate Type B leniency applications.  Type B leniency is available even after an investigation has begun as long as the “[t]he Division, at the time the corporation comes in, does not yet have evidence against the company that is likely to result in a sustainable conviction.”[2]  A whistleblower, therefore, does not preclude the granting of a leniency application in the investigation.

Here are couple of realistic scenarios where an individual whistleblower, if protected from retaliation and compensated for the enormous financial cost of exposing a cartel, might come forward, either to start an investigation or greatly advance an existing investigation:

Whistleblower Illustration 1: A sales representative who is assigned to attend working group meetings.  Once there is word of an investigation, this type of whistleblower may come forward.  Type B Corporate Leniency would still be available to one company and once an investigation obtains credibility/inevitability, the odds of a company breaking ranks and seeking that one leniency are high.

Whistleblower Illustration 2: An estimator who is told to give bid prices to a competitors.  When the authors were in the Philadelphia office, we started numerous grand jury investigations that were far from sure things.  We would be doing cartwheels in the hall if this type of whistleblower came forward when subpoenas were served. In all likelihood, however, we would need more witnesses and documents before the indictable evidence threshold was reached and  leniency was unavailable.  With an insider cooperating, the likelihood of a company seeking Type B leniency is high.

In either of these situations, not only would a whistleblower be able to start/enhance a credible grand jury investigation, but the opportunity might exist for search warrants, consensual monitoring and other investigative techniques that can greatly collapse the time and resources needed to uncover, prosecute and extinguish a cartel.

2)  An Individual Whistleblower Program Would Have a Positive Effect on Corporate Compliance Programs

Concern has been expressed that an individual whistleblower program would undermine corporate compliance programs because an individual could go directly to the government and financially benefit from exposing an existing a cartel instead of first bringing it to the attention of the corporation.  We agree that antitrust compliance programs are a positive part of a corporate culture but we disagree that an individual whistleblower statute would discourage effective corporate compliance programs. We believe a cartel whistleblower statute would make antitrust compliance programs even more necessary because the risk of getting caught would be increased.

The need for a corporate compliance program is related in part to the possibility of wrongdoing being exposed.  The words of “Not Quite A Crazy As he Used To Be ‘Crazy Eddie’” might be the lead in to every antitrust compliance program if there was a cartel whistleblower statute:

            In the two decades I was deeply involved in the Crazy Eddie fraud, the only threat made us lose sleep at night was the possibility of a whistleblower blowing the lid on our crimes. Consistent studies by the Association of Certified Fraud Examiners have shown that most frauds are exposed by whistleblowers, far ahead of frauds exposed by any other source. The SEC will be handing a gift to white-collar criminals if it reduces whistleblower bounties.

Sam E. Antar, Former Crazy Eddie CFO, former CPA, and a convicted felon.[3]

Also, as noted, even with a credible whistleblower coming forward, the Antitrust Division still has a corporate leniency in its cooperation arsenal.  Both authors, when we were with the Antitrust Division, successfully used affirmative amnesty—approaching a subject corporation, making a reverse proffer of their involvement in a cartel and giving a deadline for coming forward with a corporate leniency application.  If a whistleblower comes forward, the Division can learn what type of compliance program that company had and make a decision about whether an affirmative amnesty approach may be justified.  Of course, it may be the whistleblower did not report the matter internally because the CEO was involved directly. Or perhaps the whistleblower did complain internally and was shut down.  Or maybe the company had a good compliance program and this was a mid-level hatched conspiracy.  In any event, the existence of a whistleblower does not rule out the possibility of leniency for the whistleblower’s company. Moreover, even if the company does not obtain the leniency, the Antitrust Division has other ways of rewarding a robust—but ultimately unsuccessful whistleblower program.

Let’s Have A Criminal Cartel Whistleblower Roundtable—Please

 The Antitrust Division has commendably held roundtables on a number of potential policy issues/changes.  A roundtable on this issue “Should there be a whistleblower award for individuals who expose criminal antitrust cartels?” would be a great way to get divergent views on whether and how individual cartel whistleblowers should be rewarded.

 

[1]  One contributing factor to the apparent decline in leniency applications may be a dramatic reduction in “hot documents” that cartel members—particularly foreign members –are creating.  After a decade of being put in jail in the United States and hunted down with Red Notices and border watches, it is likely that cartel members have gotten the message that they (and their records) are not beyond the reach of the US antitrust laws.  Hopefully, this has resulted in a reduction in the formation of cartels.  It most assuredly has led to a decrease in the amount of explicit cartel emails/documents/travel records that are created.  The lack of “hot documents” must also factor into a companies’ decision about whether to seek Type A leniency.  The fewer hot documents are being created, the greater the need for individuals to come forward.

[2] Antitrust Division Corporate Leniency Policy (1993), available at https://www.justice.gov/atr/file/810281/download.

[3] Mr. Antar was commenting on why he thought it was a bad idea for the SEC to put a cap on the dollar amount of whistleblower award.  Wall Street Journal, June 29, 2018, SEC Seeks Right to Cut Whistleblower Bounties, available at https://www.wsj.com/articles/sec-proposes-whistleblower-awards-for-smaller-cases-1530212390.

Thanks for reading.  Due to technical difficulties (and blog owner IT incompetency), the comment link on this blog is not working.  Please feel free to contact me at

[email protected]

or LinkedIn

 

 

Filed Under: Blog

Antitrust Division International Deputy Addresses Enforcement Policy on State Owned Companies

May 8, 2019 by Robert Connolly

On Tuesday May 7, 2019, Deputy Assistant Attorney General Roger Alford spoke at the 2019 China Competition Policy Forum in Hainan, China.   Mr. Alford’s prepared remarks can be found here.

Mr. Alford’s remarks were largely about agency cooperation in international antitrust enforcement. He discussed the Multilateral Framework on Procedures in Competition Law Investigation and Enforcement (“MFP”).  The MFP strengthened and promoted due process in global competition law enforcement, and helped improve cooperation among competition agencies around the world.

Mr. Alford concluded his remarks by warning that state-owned enterprises (i.e. companies owned in whole or in part by the Chinese government) were not immune to investigation and prosecution for competition law violations:

Turning to the role of state-owned-enterprises, over the past few decades, SOEs have increasingly played a more prominent role in international commerce.  In fact, some of the largest companies in the world are SOEs, including numerous Chinese companies.  To the extent those companies engage in anticompetitive commercial behavior that harms the United States market, the Antitrust Division will challenge such behavior and subject foreign SOEs “to the U.S. antitrust laws to the same extent as the activities of privately owned firms.”  As Assistant Attorney General Makan Delrahim said last year, in the United States state-owned enterprises that are engaged in commercial activity are not immune from the antitrust laws and “where competitors come together to engage in collusive or anticompetitive behavior, we will bring all our enforcement tools to bear.”

Last month the Antitrust Division filed a statement of interest interpreting the scope of the commercial activity exception to foreign sovereign immunity.  As we noted in that filing, “actions of a foreign company to join and act in furtherance of an antitrust conspiracy can cause a direct effect in the United States even if that company made no direct sales in the United States.”  Any other interpretation “could immunize many conspirators from liability for their anticompetitive actions, even when the conspiracy substantially harms consumers in the United States.”

In addition, the mere fact that a foreign government owns shares in a company does not render that company an SOE that benefits from foreign sovereign immunity.  For a company to enjoy such immunity, it must be majority-owned by a foreign government or engage in a public activity on behalf of the foreign government such that it is an organ of the state.  “While commercial enterprises can qualify as organs of a foreign state in certain circumstances, they do not constitute organs when they are acting to maximize profits rather than pursue public objectives on behalf of the foreign state.”

Investigation of any state-owned enterprise would face unusual obstacles, but its good to fire a warning shot and let it be known that prosecution is not off the table.

Mr. Alford’s full remarks can be found here.

Thanks for reading.

Bob Connolly

[email protected]

 

Filed Under: Blog

Careers/Positions in the Antitrust Division, United States Dept. of Justice

May 8, 2019 by Robert Connolly

Anyone who has ever worked in the Antitrust Division, U.S. Department of Justice has described it as the best job they ever had.  I’m included in that group.  So when I noticed what looked like an unusually large number of experienced attorney job positions being advertised, I thought I’d pass on the USA jobs link here.

There are various positions being advertised on both the civil and criminal side.  If you’re interested, good luck.   If you have any questions, I might be able to help answer them.

Bob Connolly

[email protected].

Filed Under: Blog

DOJ Antitrust Division Issued Its Annual Newsletter

March 30, 2019 by Robert Connolly

On Thursday March 28th the Antitrust Division issued the press release below with a link to its annual newsletter:

The Department of Justice’s Antitrust Division today issued the 2019 edition of its annual Spring Newsletter on its website. The Newsletter highlights the Antitrust Division’s recent activities and successes on civil and criminal enforcement, international cooperation, and competition advocacy. The Newsletter also includes a message from Assistant Attorney General Makan Delrahim.

“In early March 2019, the Division announced this year’s Antitrust AAG Awards, and I encouraged those in attendance to take a moment to remember what they commemorate first and foremost: victories for the American consumer,” said Assistant Attorney General Delrahim in his ‘Message from Makan.’  “Those victories did not come easy. Each of the Division’s attorneys answered the call to public service. They worked long and often unpredictable hours in the office, on the road, and in the courtroom. Every time, though, they came back eager for the next opportunity to do what they do best: represent the United States of America in its mission to enforce the antitrust laws. As we embark on the next year of antitrust enforcement, that mission will carry on.”

The Newsletter highlights these milestones and accomplishments, and features profiles of Division leadership and staff. It can be found at https://www.justice.gov/atr/division-operations/division-update-spring-2019.

Filed Under: Blog

The End Is Near For the Per Se Rule in Criminal Antitrust Prosecutions 

March 21, 2019 by Robert Connolly

Bob Connolly  [email protected]

             I have been very interested in constitutional challenges to the per se rule in criminal Section 1 Sherman Act prosecutions.  I have reluctantly come to the conclusion that the per se rule is unconstitutional.  I say “reluctantly” because I do believe that cartels are “the supreme evil of antitrust” and I offer some fixes to still maintain a robust cartel enforcement program.

I have two versions of the article.  I posted the full version on the SSRN website (here)  and very much appreciate any comments for those that are interested.  I have a shorter version on Law 360 (here) but this is behind a firewall.  If you don’t have Law 360, you can email me and I’ll send a copy.

This is the opening paragraph of the article on Law 360:

**************************************

The per se rule for horizontal price-fixing and bid-rigging has been entrenched in  Supreme Court jurisprudence since at least United States v. Socony-Vacuum Oil Co., in 1940. That may change in the near future.

Challenges in lower courts to the per se rule have become more frequent. While these challenges have been repelled by Supreme Court precedent, the current Supreme Court may be receptive to revisiting the per se rule.

Justices Sonia Sotomayor and Neil Gorsuch, while representing so-called different wings of the Supreme Court, have taken an interest in cases where the defendant claims he has been denied the right to a jury trial. Justice Gorsuch’s bent as a “textualist” will also find support from other justices to hold that the Supreme Court improperly created the per se rule. While members of the Supreme Court will take different approaches, the per se jury instruction in criminal Sherman Act trials will fall.

In a per se case, the court, not the jury, decides whether the alleged agreement violated the Sherman Act. The jury only decides whether the charged agreement existed and whether the defendant joined the agreement. Justices Gorsuch and Sotomayor will lead a majority to hold that: (1) the per se rule is a substantive rule of law, which only Congress, not the Supreme Court can create; and (2) this substantive per se rule improperly takes away the defendant’s Sixth Amendment right to have the jury be the fact finder regarding whether the agreement charged in a Sherman Act indictment actually was a restraint of trade.

****************************************************

Thanks for reading Bob Connolly   [email protected]

The End Is Near for the Per Se Rule in Criminal Antitrust Cases:

https://www.law360.com/competition/articles/1141024/how-per-se-rule-will-die-in-criminal-antitrust-cases

The End Is Near for the Per Se Rule in Criminal Antitrust Cases: https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3356731

 

Filed Under: Blog

Heir Locators:  Now A Per Se Production

February 25, 2019 by Robert Connolly

United States v. Kemp & Associates and Daniel Mannix, Case No., 2:16-cr-403 (DS). JudgeSamPerSeMemorandum

On August 17, 2016 the defendants in this case were indicted on one count of violating §1 of the Sherman Act by agreeing to allocate customers of heir location services sold in the United States.  Utah District Court Judge David Sam initially agreed with the defendants that the case should be tried under the Rule of Reason.  Judge Sam also granted the defendants’ motion to dismiss the indictment based on the statute of limitations. The Tenth Circuit issued a decision reversing the statute of limitations dismissal.  The Tenth Circuit also encouraged the court to reconsider its Rule of Reason decision.  While noting that it did not have statutory authority to overturn the district court’s decision regarding application of the Rule of Reason, the appellate court opinion highlighted Supreme Court and Tenth Circuit cases finding customer allocation schemes to be per se Sherman Act violations. United States v. Kemp & Assocs., Inc.,907 F.3d 1264, 1278 (10th Cir. 2018). Last Thursday, February 20, 2019, upon the government’s motion for reconsideration, the District Court reversed itself and held that the case would be tried under the per se rule.

This is a victory for the Antitrust Division.  The per se rule has come under attack in numerous cases, and in each case the Antitrust Division has repelled the assault by citing abundant Supreme Court and lower court precedent applying the per se rule to certain agreements among horizontal competitors (price fixing, bid rigging and market allocation). After reconsideration, Judge Sam ruled as precedent dictated he must; that the customer allocation scheme alleged in the indictment would be tried as a per se case.

While Judge Sam was bound by precedent, I believe his instincts regarding applying the rule of reason were correct.  In any criminal case, the jury should be the fact-finder determining whether the agreement in question violated the Sherman Act, i.e. was the agreement a restraint of trade?  The operative text of the Sherman Act “every contract…in restraint of trade is declared illegal” cannot be read to allow the Court to decide as a matter of law (per se) that some agreements restrain trade and are illegal, but allow the jury to decide in other cases whether the agreement restrained trade.  In a criminal Sherman Act case, the key issue is whether the defendants’ agreement/conduct restrained trade.  Under the Sixth Amendment, only the jury can make that finding.

This, however, is not the state of the law today. Under current Supreme Court precedent, the Court is the initial fact-finder, and if the court finds the agreement fits the per se box, then the question of whether the agreement restrained trade is taken away from the jury.  In another case where the per se rule was challenged, one Ninth Circuit judge recently said, in sympathy with the argument that the jury must be the fact-finder, “I think if it’s going to get straightened out [whether the per se rule is constitutional] it’s going to have to require either an en banc panel of this court or more likely the Supreme Court itself.”[1]

Just as a mental exercise, however, suppose there was no Supreme Court per se precedent. The use of a per serule in by a trial court in a criminal antitrust case where the defendant can go to jail for ten years looks puzzling (puzzling in the sense that it is unconstitutional). Below are a few statements from Judge Sam’s recent opinion that are correct statements of law, but problematic when the Sherman Act is used as a felony criminal statute:

  • “In applying the Rule of Reason, the factfinder weighs all attendant circumstances of a case, and then decides whether the practice imposes an unreasonable restraint on competition. Continental T.V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania Inc., 433 U.S. 36, 49 (1977).”   Memorandum and Order at 2.

            This seems correct.  The fact-finder decides whether the practice violates the law.  But there is a limitation—in a Rule of Reason case.

  • “If the government can prove that such an agreement [per se] exists, then the analysis ends without inquiry into the possible economic benefits the agreement could bring. In re Cox Enters., Inc., 871 F.3d 1093, 1097 (10th Cir. 2017).”   Memorandum and Order at 3.

            This is where the per se rule goes off track.  Here, the fact-finder is the court.  And if the court finds the agreement fits into the per se box, then the jury has no role in deciding whether the government proved an element of the criminal statute beyond a reasonable doubt.

  • This [the per se rule] provides an evidentiary shortcut through the Rule of Reason’s minutiae; in such cases, the Per Se approach is justified based on efficiency. Arizona v. Maricopa Cty. Med. Soc’y., 457 U.S. 332, 344 (1982).   Memorandum and Order at 3.

  Yikes!  “Mr. Defendant, the court is going to skip over all that ‘minutiae stuff’ because it’s much more efficient this way.  Hope you don’t mind.  What’s that? Yes, the statutory maximum is ten years in jail.”

  • Thus,‘[i]t is only after considerable experience with certain business relationships that courts classify them as per se violations of the Sherman Act.”’ United States v. Topco, Inc., 405 U.S. 596, 607- 08 (1972) (emphasis added).   Memorandum and Order at 3.

This statement in Topco is pretty ironic.  The Supreme Court, not a jury, found the territorial allocation among Topco supermarkets to be a per se violation.  Today, most commentators would argue the Supreme Court got it wrong and the intra-brand agreements did not restrain trade, but in fact promoted inter-brand competition.  Luckily, I’m pretty sure no one went to jail in Topco.  I think part of the reason little thought was given to the defendants’ Sixth Amendment rights to have a jury decide questions of fact, was that the Sherman Act was a misdemeanor, and no one went to jail [except the occasional troublesome labor leader].  And, the Apprendi, Booker line of Sixth Amendment jurisprudence had not yet been developed.

  • “Certain factors can negate application of the Per Se approach when it would be otherwise applicable. See, Nat’l Collegiate Athletic Ass’n, 468 U.S. at 103. This court must analyze whether any of these factors apply to the present case.  Memorandum and Order at 7.

            Judge Sam noted that even in horizonal agreements among competitors, there are exceptions to the per se rule.  Some cases that look like a per se violation may not be a per se violation, but the fact-finder is the court.  In a criminal case, the fact-finder should be the jury.  Can you imagine in a fraud case the Judge saying “Oh, the indictment alleges a swamp land sale in Florida to an elderly widow.”  That’s “always or almost always” going to be fraud, so let’s skip over that part and just have the jury decide “Did you sell her the land?”

       Heir Locators is a timely and interesting case for me.  To be clear, I am not criticizing Judge Sam who has correctly applied controlling precedent.  But, I have been thinking a lot about whether the per se rule is unquestioned gospel truth, but in reality, under todays’ Sixth Amendment jurisprudence only the jury can be the fact-finder on an element of a criminal offense—and the most critical one at that—did the defendant restrain trade?

I believe that the per se rule will be found unconstitutional (or perhaps I will be found to be an idiot) when a criminal antitrust case reaches the Supreme Court.  It may be sooner rather than later.

Stay tuned!

Bob Connolly    [email protected]

 

[1] Mlex, Joshua Sisco, January 16, 2019 “In foreclosure auction appeal, court questions applicability of per se standard, (behind firewall).

 

Filed Under: Blog

Dr. Ai Deng on Algorithmic Antitrust Compliance

February 19, 2019 by Robert Connolly

Below is a post by Ai Deng, Phd of NERA Economic Consulting on Algorithmic Antitrust Compliance

****************************************

I had the distinct honor of offering live testimony last November on the issue of algorithmic collusion at the FTC’s Hearings on Competition and Consumer Protection in the 21st Century. And having written a lot about the “dark side” of algorithms (see, here [https://ssrn.com/abstract=3029662], here [https://ssrn.com/abstract=3082514], and here [https://ssrn.com/abstract=3171315]), I think it is time to explore how algorithms could help with antitrust compliance. This is the topic of my most recent article. You can download the full working paper at https://papers.ssrn.com/abstract=3334164

Abstract

If pricing algorithms could autonomously collude, can they be made automatic antitrust compliant as well? That is the question many have started pondering after a series of public comments by EU competition officials in recent years. In this paper, I propose a multi-faceted approach to algorithmic compliance. I draw lessons from the recent AI literature and discuss some potential technical frameworks for compliant algorithmic design.

Keywords: algorithmic pricing, algorithmic collusion, artificial intelligence, antitrust, compliance

As always, I appreciate your thoughts and comments. You can reach me at [email protected] or connect with me on LinkedIn [here]

_________________________________________

Ai Deng, PhD
Associate Director

NERA
ECONOMIC CONSULTING

1255 23rd Street NW,

Washington, DC, 20037

Tel: +1 (202) 4669210

Fax: +1 (202) 4669252
[email protected]
www.nera.com

Filed Under: Blog

New Article on the Need for A Criminal Antitrust Whistleblower Statute

February 13, 2019 by Robert Connolly

I want to thank my friend Jeffrey May of Wolters Kluwer Antitrust Law Daily for helping to get my new article, with Kimberly Justice, published.  Below is the summary of the article by the Antitrust Law Daily with a link to the article itself.

STRATEGIC PERSPECTIVES: Former Antitrust Division prosecutors say time is now for criminal antitrust whistleblower statute

By WK Editorial Staff

With the Republican Senate, new House Democratic majority, and the expected confirmation of William Barr as Attorney General, the political situation is now ripe for the adoption of such a statute.

2018 was a record-breaking year for the SEC and CFTC’s whistleblowing programs, but there was no story at the U.S. Department of Justice Antitrust Division because there is no antitrust whistleblower statute, write Robert Connolly and Kimberly Justice, two former prosecutors with the Antitrust Division, United States Department of Justice. In their article, “The Political Stars Align for a Criminal Antitrust Whistleblower Statute,” they argue that the political situation is now favorable for the adoption of such a statute. The Republican controlled Senate has favored criminal antitrust whistleblower protection in the past, and the new House Democratic majority will be receptive to antitrust whistleblower legislation. Moreover, the expected confirmation of William Barr as Attorney General may swing the Justice Department behind a robust cartel whistleblower statute.

************************************************************************

Ms. Justice and I have a previous whistleblower related article published by Wolters Kluwer: It’s A Crime There Isn’t a Criminal Antitrust Whistleblower Statute

Thanks for reading.

If you have any ideas about how I may push this agenda with the people who matter, please contact me:

Bob Connolly      [email protected]

Filed Under: Blog

2019 ABA Antitrust Section Spring Meeting–March 26-29

January 29, 2019 by Robert Connolly

I just registered for the ABA Antitrust Section Spring Meeting in Washington DC, March 26-29th. I thought folks might like to know that early bird registration ends February 5, 2019.

From the announcement:

On March 26-29, please join us for the 67th Spring Meeting of the Section of Antitrust Law where competition and consumer protection meet. Last year we had over 3300 delegates from 65 countries. Early Bird registration ends on February 5th, 2019.

For full details and to register, visit here.

Hope to see you there.

Bob Connolly [email protected]

Filed Under: Blog

A Comment on the Fugitive Disentitlement Doctrine

January 24, 2019 by Robert Connolly

I have written before about the fugitive disentitlement doctrine and a recent case about the fugitive disentitlement doctrine caught my attention. United States v. Contoguris, Case: 2:17-cr-00233-EAS (SD Ohio).  It is not an antitrust case but does involve the interplay of the global reach of certain US criminal statutes and the fugitive disentitlement doctrine. 

The defendant is Armenia’s former ambassador to China who was charged with conspiracy to commit money laundering. He is a foreign national who has never set foot in the United States.  He resides in China, which has no extradition treaty with the U.S., and has deliberately avoided coming to the U.S., and therefore remains a fugitive despite U.S. efforts to take him into custody.  The defendant filed a motion to dismiss certain counts in the indictment as facially invalid for various reason including arguing that the statute (18 U.S.C. Section 1956) expressly forbids extraterritorial application.  The government asked that the motion be held in abeyance while the defendant remained a fugitive. The defendant argued that the fugitive disentitlement doctrine should not be applied because he is not a fugitive.   

The court noted that “Under the fugitive disentitlement doctrine a fugitive is not entitled to call upon the resources of the court until he submits to jurisdiction, citing Molinaro v. New Jersey, 396 U.S. 365, 366 (1970). The court then addressed two questions: 1) was the defendant a fugitive? and 2) did any special circumstances exist that warrant an exception to the doctrine’s application?

The court rejected the argument that the defendant was not a fugitive because he did not flee stating “Merely being aware of charges and refusing t submit to arrest triggers the fugitive status.  The court acknowledged that in In re Hijazi, 589 F. 3d 401 (7th Cir. 2009) the Seventh Circuit found special circumstances existed and directed the district court to rule on Hijazi’s motions to dismiss.  Some of the special circumstances were the travel restrictions Hijazi faced. In this case, the court found no special circumstances, “He [the defendant] can continue living with his spouse in China during an abatement period.”   The court concluded that the defendant was a fugitive and that he was not entitled to hear his motion heard until he showed up and submitted to jurisdiction

The fugitive disentitlement doctrine is of interest to me because the Antitrust Division indicts many foreign nationals.  I don’t think the numbers are published but there are dozens of fugitives from Antitrust Division indictments.  I know because I indicted quite a few foreign nationals when I was with the Division.  With some exceptions (voluntary surrender or apprehension on a Red Notice) the fugitives stay fugitives indefinitely. 

In the case discussed above, the defendant moved to dismiss counts in the indictment as facially invalid. The court applied the fugitive disentitlement doctrine and refused to consider the motion.  I think this was wrong (although in this case, since even a successful challenge would have eliminated only certain counts, it made sense for the court to defer any rulings until the entire case was before him). The rationale for the doctrine applies most strongly when a fugitive wants to be tried in absentia.  Who wouldn’t? You win and you’re free; you lose and you keep running.  The same with an appeal after conviction; you flee and appeal.  You have nothing to lose.  In these cases, it would be wrong to make the government and court go through the time and expense when the defendant has no skin in the game.  But a situation where a foreign fugitive attacks the facial validity of indictment is different.  The mere indictment imposes a significant penalty on a foreign defendant.  In antitrust cases, the defendant is put on an Interpol Red Notice and his ability to travel is extremely limited. For most international businesspersons this means a career end.  If the fugitive does come to the United States and submit to jurisdiction, he has to spend a significant amount of time here, likely with no job, maybe in jail and away from family.  In this case it is the government with no, or very little skin in the game.  An indictment can be returned with severe ramifications for the foreign defendant, with very little chance the government will ever be put to its proof because the cost to a foreign fugitive to come to the US is too high. 

The foreign fugitive by definition faces “special circumstances” mention by the Hijazi court. This should lead to a balancing test by a Judge before applying the doctrine. At one end of the spectrum, a foreign defendant should not be able to try a case in abstentia, for the same reasons a domestic fugitive cannot.  Nor should a foreign defendant get wholesale discovery to “test” the strength of the case before deciding to show up.  At the other end of the spectrum, a challenge to the indictment itself should be allowed. This won’t come up often but could in the context of the application of the FTAIA [Foreign Trade Antitrust Improvement Act].  Without any ability (or very limited) ability of a foreign defendant to challenge the applicability of the FTAIA there is little restraint on the government determining the outer most application.  Courts, not the government unilaterally, should be the arbiter of the reach of US criminal statutes. A challenge to the facial validity of the indictment uses relatively little government and court resources while having enormous potential benefit to a defendant wrongfully charged.  Another situation may be the statute of limitations.  This may require some discovery and government and judicial resources, but again, balancing the right of a foreign defendant to make a facial challenge to the indictment should justify the expenditure.  Application of the ffd would be case specific, but courts should recognize the “special circumstances” of a foreign defendant as opposed to a US fugitive on the run.

I have written more about the fugitive disentitlement doctrine with a Masayuki Atsumi; a distinguished Japanese lawyer who is also licensed in the United States.  He has an LLM from the University of Chicago.  Mr. Atsumi is a Founding Partner in Miura & Partners -Japan. We wrote two Cartel Capers blog posts:

The Fugitive Disentitlement Doctrine Part 1 (here) and Part 2 (here). We also published a longer article in a highly regarded Japanese legal publication (here)

Thanks for reading.

Bob Connolly [email protected].


            

Filed Under: Blog

  • « Previous Page
  • 1
  • …
  • 7
  • 8
  • 9
  • 10
  • 11
  • …
  • 36
  • Next Page »

Search this site

The US Supreme Court has called cartels "the supreme evil of antitrust." Price fixing and bid rigging may not be all that evil as far as supreme evils go, but an individual can get 10 years in jail and corporations can be fined hundreds of millions of dollars. This blog will provide news, insight and analysis of the world of cartels based on the many years my colleagues and I have as former feds with the Antitrust Division, USDOJ.

© Copyright 2014 Cartel Capers · All Rights Reserved